Academia.edu no longer supports Internet Explorer.
To browse Academia.edu and the wider internet faster and more securely, please take a few seconds to upgrade your browser.
1987, Review of Regional Studies
A rather large body of recent literature has explored the implications of various conjectural variations in spatial pricing models. Very different conclusions have been reached as to which conjecture is appropriate for spatial modeling. The purpose of this paper is to add to this debate through application to a spatial model of two sets of arguments which stress that entrepreneurs learn.
Geographical Analysis, 2010
Journal of Regional Science, 1994
ABSTRACT. This paper examines medium-run and long-run equilibria in unbounded (circular) and bounded (linear) one-dimensional multifirm markets. A price-location adjustment model is outlined that dows simulation of the spatial equilibrium when these firms anticipate reactions from their nearest spatial rivals. Thus, the market equilibrium is derived from the interdependent but atomistic decisions of the competing firms and is not imposed by some outside observer or agency. Ail conjectures are exogenous; the three well-known price conjectures (Greenhut-Ohta, Hotelling-Smithies, and Losch) are highlighted; and the relevant comparative statics are provided.
Journal of Urban Economics, 1984
Free entry in Liischian spatial competition leads to a tangency between each firm's negatively sloped average revenue and the downsloping portion of average costs-as in Chamberlin's monopolistic competition. It is generally concluded that this equilibrium involves too many inefficiently small firms. However, this conclusion is incorrect. 'Ihe difference between price and firm marginal production costs in spatial equilibrium is just sufficient to cover the additional marginal cost of output resulting from availability of multiple locations. This Chamberlinian tangency does not imply inefficiency, because it does not include all the social costs and benefits resulting from spatial competition. 'I thank M. L. Greenhut, Thomas Cosimano, and Hiroshi Ohta for helpful comments as I developed this model. 'Spatial competition does not really fit the textbook monopolistic competition model that is most closely associated with Chamberlin [28]. Rather, spatial competition more closely fits the linked oligopoly model which Chamberlin discussed [ll, pp. 103,104]. However, with entry to zero profits these oligopoly firms end up with demand curves tangent to the downsloping section of their average cost curves.
Geographical Analysis, 2010
This article provides a general overview of spatial economics, which covers location theory, spatial competition, and regional and urban economics. After a brief review of the main theoretical traditions, the fundamental role of non-convexities and imperfect competition is highlighted. The main challenges faced by theoretical and empirical research are also discussed, followed by a broader discussion of the relationship between this field of research and other subfields of economics and other disciplines. What is spatial economics? In a nutshell, spatial economics is concerned with the allocation of (scarce) resources over space and the location of economic activity. Depending on how this definition is read, the realm of spatial economics may be either extremely broad or rather narrow. On the one hand, economic activity has to take place somewhere so that spatial economics may be concerned with anything that economics is concerned about. On the other hand, location analysis focuses mostly on one economic question, namely, location choice. This is only one decision among a large number of economic decisions. Which boundaries for spatial economics? In practice, we can distinguish three sets of questions for which the importance of the spatial dimension is very different. Consider first the core questions of spatial economics. For example, why are there cities? Why do some regions prosper while others do not? Why do we observe residential segregation? Why do firms from the same industry cluster? These are intrinsically 'spatial' questions, that is, questions in which the spatial dimension plays a dominant
The Quarterly Journal of Austrian Economics, 2005
2011
Hotelling's (1929) principle of minimum differentiation and the alternative prediction that firms will maximally differentiate from their rivals in order to relax price competition have not been explicitly tested so far. We report results from experimental spatial duopolies designed to address this issue. The levels of product differentiation observed are systematically lower than predicted in equilibrium under risk neutrality and compatible with risk aversion. The observed prices are consistent with collusion attempts. Our main findings are robust to variations in three experimental conditions: automated vs. human market sharing rule for ties, individual vs. collective decision making, and even vs. odd number of locations.
The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance, 2005
This paper offers some preliminary steps in the marriage of some of the theoretical foundations of the new economic geography with spatial computable general equilibrium models. Modeling the spatial economy of Brazil using the usual assumptions of CGE models makes little sense when one state, São Paulo, accounts for 40% of GDP and where transportation costs are high and accessibility low compared to European or North American standards. Hence, handling market imperfections becomes imperative as does the need to address internal spatial issues from the perspective of Brazil's increasing involvement with external markets such as MERCOSUL, EU, NAFTA. The paper builds on the B-MARIA-27, a multiregional CGE model of the Brazilian economy; non-constant returns and non-iceberg transportation costs are introduced and some simulation exercises carried out. The results, limited in this paper to short-run considerations, confirm the asymmetric impacts that transportation investment has on a spatial economy in which one state (São Paulo) is able to more fully exploit scale economies vis a vis the rest of Brazil. The analysis also reveals the importance of parameter estimation in handling imperfectly competitive markets.
Review of Regional Studies, 1979
typically uses concentration ratios in antitrust litigations to demonstrate the degree of monopoly power as well as the anti competitive impact of mergers.' However, the empirical evidence of the link between concentration and competitive performance (i.e., price levels) as well as between concentration and profits, generally shows only a weak relation ship, if any at all.^ Furthermore, the theoretical foundations of the assumed causal relationship going from concentration of ownership to market power and profits has been challenged."' The typical argument has been that this causal relationship runs from concentration to higher price to profits, generally as a consequence of collusion. An alternative argument stressed by Demsetz [14] and Peltzman [22], is that causality runs from concentration to average cost to profits, as a result of improved production efficiency. The pur pose of the following presentation is to add another voice to those challenging regulators' (and a large number of economists') reliance on the assumption of a concentration to a higher collusive price to market power causal relation ship. We do so by examining certain implications of spatial price theory.'' In particular we shall see that: 1) entry and reduced concentration may lead to higher prices (prices and concentration can be inversely related), 2) the type of spatial competition which involves the largest number of firms in a spatially competitive equilibrium (and therefore the lowest level of concentration), also involves the highest prices, and 3) a merger of spatially separated firms in the same spatially competitive geographic market need not result in higher prices since the spatially competitive price maximizes total profits. Profits cannot rise through collusive price increases.' Thus, the typical argument of con centration to price to profit relationship does not hold in cases where both firms and consumers are spatially dispersed and distance is costly. THE IMPACT OF ENTRY ON A SPATIAL MONOPOLIST'S PRICE Assume we have a single firm located at point A in Figure 1. This firm is selling a product to spatially dispersed consumers located along the line AB. Consumers must pay the firm's price (mill price) plus delivery costs to their location. Thus, the relevant demand to the spatial monopolist is the aggrega
Geographical Analysis, 2010
This paper investigates the properties of two types of cost restrictions that guarantee the existence of an equilibrium in pure strategies in Bayesian spatial competition models with heterogenous firms.
Dans cet article, nous considérons uneéconomie spatiale de propriété privée. Nous pouvons distinguer deux différences essentielles entre notre modèle et le modèle classique d'Arrow-Debreu. Tout d'abord, chaque consommateur doit choisrà l'équilibre un unique endroit où consommer. La deuxième différence concerne les dotations initiales qui dépendent du choix de résidence du consommateur, de manièreà prendre en compte principalement la dotation en travail. Nous démontrons alors l'existence d'unéquilibre général.
Annals of Regional Science, 1991
Regional Science and Urban Economics, 2010
We study the relationship between competition and quality within a spatial competition framework where firms compete in prices and quality. We generalise existing literature on spatial price–quality competition along several dimensions, including utility functions that are non-linear in income and cost functions that are non-separable in output and quality. Our main message is that the scope for a positive relationship between competition and quality is underestimated in the existing literature. If we allow for income effects by assuming that ...
2011
This critical review focuses on the development of spatial competition models in which the location choice by firms plays a major role. Theref o , after a brief review of the roots of spatial competition modeling, this paper intends to offer a critical analysis over its recent developments. The starting point is the recognition of the increased importance of this topic through the quantification of the research in this field by using some bibliometric tools. After that, this study proceeds by identifying the main r esearch paths within spatial competition modeling. Specifically, the type of strategy (Bertr and vs. Cournot competition) and its implications over location equilibria are discussed . A ditionally, it is presented a comparison of the effects on the location equilibria of the mo st typical assumptions in literature, that respect to the market (linear vs. circular), produc tion costs, transportation costs, as well as the number of firms. Finally, the type of information ( c...
Cutting Edge Conference, RICS, …, 1998
T h e n a t u r e a n d s t r u c t u r e o f s p a t i a l i n d u s t r i a l p r o p e r t y m a r k e t s N e i l D u n s e , U n i v e r s i t y o f A b e r d e e n , C o l i n J o n e s , H e r i o t -W a t t U n i v e r s i t y, a n d D a v i d M a r t i n a n d W i l l Fr a s e r, P a i s l e y U n i v e r s i t y I S B N 0 -8 5 4 0 6 -9 46-1
Regional Science and Urban Economics, 2008
This paper establishes the existence and efficiency of equilibrium in a local public goods economy with spatial structures by formalizing Hamilton's (1975 Urban Studies) elaboration of Tiebout's (1956 JPE) tale. We use a well-known equilibrium concept from Rothschild and Stiglitz (1976, QJE) in a market with asymmetric information, and show that Hamilton's zoning policy plays an essential role in proving the existence and efficiency of equilibrium. We use an idealized large economy following Ellickson, Grodal, Scotchmer and Zame (1999, Econometrica) and Allouch, Conley and Wooders (2004). Our theorem is directly applicable to the existence and efficiency of a discrete spatial approximation of mono-or multi-centric city equilibria in an urban economy with commuting time costs, even if we allow the existence of multiple qualities of (collective) residences, when externalities due to traffic congestion are not present.
Economics Letters, 2010
This paper investigates the properties of two types of cost restrictions that guarantee the existence of an equilibrium in pure strategies in Bayesian spatial competition models with heterogenous firms.
Loading Preview
Sorry, preview is currently unavailable. You can download the paper by clicking the button above.