Academia.edu no longer supports Internet Explorer.
To browse Academia.edu and the wider internet faster and more securely, please take a few seconds to upgrade your browser.
2007, SSRN Electronic Journal
We analyze the labor market effects of neutral and investment-specific technology shocks along the intensive margin (hours worked) and the extensive margin (unemployment). We characterize the dynamic response of unemployment in terms of the job separation and the job finding rate. We find that the job separation rate accounts for a major portion of the impact response of unemployment. Over the adjustment path, instead, unemployment is mainly explained by fluctuations in the job finding rate. Neutral shocks prompt an increase in unemployment while investment specific shocks are expansionary on employment and hours worked. Neutral shocks explain a substantial portion of the volatility of unemployment and output; investment specific shocks mainly explain hours worked volatility. We show that these findings are consistent with the view that neutral technological progress prompt Schumpeterian creative destruction, while investment-specific technological progress operates essentially as in a neoclassical growth model.
2007
We analyze the labor market effects of neutral and investment-specific tech-nology shocks along the intensive margin (hours worked) and the extensive mar-gin (unemployment). We characterize the dynamic response of unemployment in terms of the job separation and the job finding rate. Labor market adjust-ments occur along the extensive margin in response to neutral shocks, along the intensive margin in response to investment specific shocks. The job separation rate accounts for a major portion of the impact response of unemployment. Neu-tral shocks prompt a contemporaneous increase in unemployment because of a sharp rise in the separation rate. This is prolonged by a persistent fall in the job finding rate. Investment specific shocks rise employment and hours worked. Neutral shocks explain a substantial portion of the volatility of unemployment and output; investment specific shocks mainly explain hours worked volatility. This suggests that neutral progress is consistent with Schumpet...
2016
We consider a version of the Solow growth model where technological progress can be investment specific or investment neutral. The labour market is subject to search frictions, and the existing productive units may fail to adopt the most recent technological advances. Technological progress can lead to the destruction of technologically obsolete jobs and cause unemployment. We calibrate the model to replicate the high persistence that characterizes the dynamics of firms ’ neutral technology and the frequency of firms ’ capital adjustment. We find that neutral technological advances increase job destruction and job reallocation and reduce aggregate employment. Investment-specific technological advances reduce job destruction, have mild effects on job creation, and are expansionary. Hence, neutral technological progress prompts Schumpeterian creative destruction, while investment-specific technological progress operates essentially as in the standard neoclassical growth model. Using s...
Journal of Monetary Economics, 2007
A positive technology shock may lead to a rise or a fall in per capita hours, depending on how hours enter the empirical VAR model. We provide evidence that, independent of how hours enter the VAR, a positive technology shock leads to a weak response in nominal wage inflation, a modest decline in price inflation, and a modest rise in the real wage on impact and a permanent rise in the long run. We then examine the abilities of several competing theories to account for the evidence. The model that stands out features sticky prices, sticky nominal wages, and habit formation. The same model also does well in accounting for the labor market evidence in the post-Volcker period.
SSRN Electronic Journal
Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden.
Recent empirical evidence suggests that a positive technology shock leads to a decline in labor inputs. However, the standard real business model fails to account for this empirical regularity. Can the presence of labor market frictions address this problem, without otherwise altering the functioning of the model? We develop and estimate a real business cycle model using Bayesian techniques that allows, but does not require, labor market frictions to generate a negative response of employment to a technology shock. The results of the estimation support the hypothesis that labor market frictions are the factor responsible for the negative response of employment.
Journal of Applied Econometrics, 2010
We analyze the effects of neutral and investment-specific technology shocks on hours and output. Long cycles in hours are captured in a variety of ways. Hours robustly fall in response to neutral shocks and robustly increase in response to investment specific shocks. The percentage of the variance of hours (output) explained by neutral shocks is small (large); the opposite is true for investment specific shocks. 'News shocks' are uncorrelated with the estimated technology shocks.
The Economic Journal, 1999
Review of Economic Dynamics, 1998
We generalize apparently contradictory results in the literature about the effect of exogenous technological progress on unemployment. We assume that new technology can be adopted either through creative job destruction or through onthe-job implementation at a cost. We show that there is a critical level of implementation cost where the effect of growth on employment switches from positive to negative at higher costs. In extensions of the model we show that gross job reallocation can increase at faster growth with no clear-cut effects on aggregate employment.
Journal of the European Economic Association, 2004
This paper contributes to the debate initiated by Gali (1999). I provide a theory with capital income taxation, labor hoarding as well as long-run shifts in the social attitudes to the work place-modelled as "leisure at the work place"-to argue that there are other shocks that may influence labor productivity in the long run. I introduce "medium-run identification" and show it to be superior to long-run identification or standard short-run identification, when applied to artificial data. With US data and medium-run identification, I find the robust result that technology shocks lead to a humpshaped response of total hours worked, which is mildly positive following a near-zero initial response.
Empirica, 2005
We analyze sector specific shocks in productivity and demand in 19 manufacturing sectors of the Austrian economy. Based on a structural vector autoregressive (SVAR) model with long run restrictions developed by Gal\'i (1999) we extract technology and non-technology shocks from sectoral andaggregate data and study their patterns and relationship by means of a principal components analysis. We find a close association of sectoral and macroeconomic non-technology shocks but only a very weak association for technology shocks. Impulse-response analysis indicates that for almost all manufacturing sectors and the Austrian economy productivity growth rates experience an immediate increase to positive technology shocks while the hours worked decline. We therefore confirm Gal\'i's results on the level of manufacturing industries. Finally, we use the identified shocks as explanatory variables in fixed effect regressions on growth rates of employment, output and investment. We find that our shocks are closely associated to employment growth and output growth but not to growth in investment. The effect of technology shocks is different on the level of manufacturing industries and the aggregate economy.
SSRN Electronic Journal, 2006
We analyze the effects of neutral and investment-specific technology shocks on hours and output. Long cycles in hours are captured in a variety of ways. Hours robustly fall in response to neutral shocks and robustly increase in response to investment specific shocks. The percentage of the variance of hours (output) explained by neutral shocks is small (large); the opposite is true for investment specific shocks. 'News shocks' are uncorrelated with the estimated technology shocks.
2010
Recent empirical evidence suggests that a positive technology shock leads to a decline in labor inputs. However, the standard real business cycle model fails to account for this empirical regularity. Can the presence of labor market frictions address this problem without otherwise altering the functioning of the model? We develop and estimate a real business cycle model using Bayesian techniques that allows but does not require labor market frictions to generate a negative response of employment to a technology shock. The results of the estimation support the hypothesis that labor market frictions are responsible for the negative response of employment.
1996
Using data for the G7 countries, Iestimate conditional correlations of employment and productivity, based on a decomposition of the two series into technology and non-technology components. The picturethatemerges is hardto reconcile with the predictions of the standardReal Business Cycle model. For a majority of countries the following resultsstand out: (a) technology shockt appear to induce a negative comovement between productivity and employment, counterbalancedby apositive comovement generatedby demandshocks, (b) the impulse responses show a persistent decline of employment in response to a positive technology shock, and (c) measured productivity increases temporarily in response to a positive demand shock. generally,the patternof economic fluctuationsattributedto technology shocks seems to be unrelatedto major postwarcyclical episodes. A simple model with monopolistic competition prices, and variable effort is shown to be able to account for the empirical findings.
Review of Economic …, 2007
We consider a version of the Solow growth model where technological progress can be investment specific or investment neutral. The labour market is subject to search frictions, and the existing productive units may fail to adopt the most recent technological advances. Technological ...
manuscript, November, 2007
We analyze the effects of neutral and investment-specific technology shocks on hours worked and unemployment. We characterize the response of unemployment in terms of job separation and job finding rates. Job separation rates mainly account for the impact ...
2006
This paper evaluates the dynamic response of worker ‡ows, job ‡ows, and vacancies to aggregate shocks in a structural vector autoregression. We identify demand, monetary, and technology shocks by imposing sign restrictions on the responses of output, in ‡ation, the interest rate, and the relative price of investment. No restrictions are placed on the responses of job and worker ‡ows variables. We …nd that both investment-speci…c and neutral technology shocks generate responses to job and worker ‡ows variables that are qualitatively similar to those induced by monetary and demand shocks. However, technology shocks have more persistent e¤ects. The job …nding rate largely drives the response of unemployment, though the separation rate explains up to one third. For job ‡ows, the destruction margin is more important than the creation margin in driving employment growth. Measuring reallocation from job ‡ows, we …nd that monetary and demand shocks do not have signi…cant e¤ects on cumulative job reallocation, whereas expansionary technology shocks have mildly negative e¤ects. We also estimate shock-speci…c matching functions. Allowing for a break in 1984:Q1 shows considerable subsample di¤erences in matching elasticities and relative shock-speci…c e¢ ciency.
2008
We analyze how unemployment, job finding and job separation rates react to neutral and investment-specific technology shocks. Neutral shocks increase unemployment and explain a substantial portion of unemployment volatility; investment-specific shocks expand employment and hours worked and mostly contribute to hours worked volatility. Movements in the job separation rates are responsible for the impact response of unemployment. Movements in the job finding rates account for its adjustment path. Our evidence qualifies the conclu- sions by Hall (2005) and Shimer (2007) and warns against using search models with exogenous separation rates to analyze the effects of technology shocks.
B E Journal of Macroeconomics, 2010
This paper studies the role of investment-specific shocks as an amplification mechanism in the labor market fluctuations. We first show evidence that suggests that when technological advances make equipment more expensive, not only investment and output decrease but also firms post fewer vacancies, hours worked are reduced and unemployment increases. Moreover, we study the quantitative impact of this type of shocks on the labor market by incorporating them into a Real Business Cycle model with search and matching frictions. We find that in our model these shocks have direct amplification effect on labor market fluctuations, increasing the volatility of the labor market variables between two and five times.
SSRN Electronic Journal, 2003
I use the neoclassical growth model to identify the effects of technology shocks on the US business cycle. The model includes two sources of technology shocks: neutral, which affect the production of all goods homogeneously, and investment-specific. Investmentspecific shocks are the unique source of the secular trend in the real price of investment goods, while both shocks are the only factors which affect labor productivity in the long run. Consistent with previous empirical work which considers only neutral shocks, the results suggest these shocks account for little, about 6 percent, of the business cycle variation in hours worked. In contrast, investment-specific shocks account for about 50 percent, a new finding which suggests that technology shocks are an important source of the business cycle.
2004
In this paper we analyse the influence of sector specific developments in productivity and demand on net entry and employment in 19 industrial sectors of the Austrian economy. Based on the model of structural dynamics of Pasinetti, we develop an identification scheme that allows us to extract technology and demand shocks, by means of a structural vector autoregressive (SVAR) model with long-run restrictions. We study the patterns of productivity and demand shocks across industries by means of a principal components analysis and find that sectoral and macro-economic developments in demand strongly correlate, while this is not the case for technology shocks. Impulse-response analysis shows that for almost all sectors productivity growth rates experience an immediate increase to positive technology shocks while the hours worked decline as conjectured by Pasinetti. Finally, we use the identified shocks as explanatory variables in time-series cross-section regressions on net-entry and employment data. Both types of shocks are able to explain dynamics on the industry level in terms of employment and sales but not firm dynamics.
Loading Preview
Sorry, preview is currently unavailable. You can download the paper by clicking the button above.