Academia.edu no longer supports Internet Explorer.
To browse Academia.edu and the wider internet faster and more securely, please take a few seconds to upgrade your browser.
2021
We estimate the relationship between GDP per capita growth and the growth rate of the national savings rate using a panel of 130 countries over the period 1960-2017. We find that GDP per capita growth increases (decreases) the growth rate of the national savings rate in poor countries (rich countries), and a higher credit-to-GDP ratio decreases the national savings rate as well as the income elasticity of the national savings rate. We develop a model with a credit constraint to explain the growth-saving relationship by the saving behavior of entrepreneurs at both the intensive and extensive margins. We further present supporting evidence for our theoretical findings by utilizing cross-country time series data of the number of new businesses registered and the corporate savings rate.
Macroeconomic Dynamics, 2021
We estimate the relationship between GDP per capita growth and the growth rate of the national saving rate using a panel of 130 countries over the period 1960–2017. We find that GDP per capita growth increases (decreases) the growth rate of the national saving rate in poor countries (rich countries), and a higher credit-to-GDP ratio decreases the national saving rate as well as the income elasticity of the national saving rate. We develop a model with a credit constraint to explain the growth-saving relationship by the saving behavior of entrepreneurs at both the intensive and extensive margins. We further present supporting evidence for our theoretical findings by utilizing cross-country time series data of the number of new businesses registered and the corporate saving rate.
2013
We study an overlapping generations model where ex-ante identical agents make an occupational choice under a borrowing constraint. Indivisible investment gives rise to entrepreneurial rents but does not allow all to become entrepreneurs. Competition alone without any shocks forces entrepreneurs to save more than workers. The model predicts that growth in national income has a positive effect on aggregate savings rates in poor countries but a negative effect in rich countries, and borrowing constraints increase aggregate savings rates as well as its response to growth in national income. These predictions are supported by empirical evidence based on panel data that covers more than 130 countries during 1960-2007.
2016
We study an overlapping generations model where ex-ante identical agents make an occupational choice under a borrowing constraint. Indivisible investment gives rise to entrepreneurial rents and does not allow everyone to become an entrepreneur. Competition forces entrepreneurs to save more than workers. The model predicts that growth in national income has a positive effect on domestic saving rates in poor countries but a negative effect in rich countries. Borrowing constraints increase domestic saving rates as well as the response of domestic saving to growth in income. These predictions are supported by empirical evidence based on panel data that covers 130 countries during 1960-2007.
Variations in growth performances across regions of the world have been of significant interest to development economists. Prior to the spectacular growth of many of the East Asian economies, a variety of structural and non-structural factors were employed to explain the differences in growth performances. Since that time, however, regional variation in growth achievement has been explained in terms of differences in savings and investment performances. It has been widely observed in the literature that some regions ( e.g., Sub-Saharan Africa and Latin America) tend to save and invest a smaller proportion of their aggregate outputs than did their more dynamic counterparts (e.g., Asia and the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development Countries (OECD)). Our interest in the linkage between savings, investment and economic growth is not new in the economic development literature. The works of Arthur Lewis in the 1950s, for example, portray the central task of economic development as that of raising the proportion of national income saved and invested from 4-5 per cent to 12-15 per cent (Lewis 1954). Recent theoretical perspectives, typified by endogenous growth models, suggest that high investment rates can result in a permanent increase in an economy's overall growth rates (Romer:·1986; Lucas 1988). Both theoretical approaches identify investment as a fundamental factor in economic growth. In contrast to developed countries, where growth- problems were viewed in the Keynesian sense of too much saving and too little spending, investment and, hence, economic growth in developing countries were constrained by the insufficiency of savings (James, et al 1987). In this context, evidence from development experiences strongly suggests that the best performing countries (even among the developing ones), have achieved this status largely on the basis of their high rates of savings and investment (Oyejide 1998). Although savings, capital formation and economic growth have been central to economic development analysis for several decades, the connection between them and the direction of causality is far from clear (Fry 1980; Schmidt-Hebbel, et al 1996). Accepting that the relationship is unidirectional (i.e., moving from saving to investment and, hence, to economic growth) may be misleading. The transformation of an initial growth spurt into sustained expansion of output requires the accumulation of capital and its corresponding financing. Expansion, in turn, sets in motion a self-reinforcing process by which the anticipation of growth encourages investment, investment supports growth, and increased income raises saving (Schmidt-Hebbel, et al 1996).
2016
While the literature, both international and in South Africa, is relatively rich in studies on the determinants of foreign direct investment as well as the determinants of savings, none of the work done on South Africa has made use of disaggregated savings data to understand whether there is an observable difference in the marginal propensity to save of the different economic sectors. Thus, this paper attempts to assess the marginal propensity to save by the household, corporate and government sectors in South Africa. The results of the econometric analysis demonstrate that the greatest responsiveness of savings to GDP growth occurs amongst corporates. These findings should inform the South African government on how to regulate sectoral taxation that intends to encourage savings, given the low level of savings in the country.
Nowadays, saving regularly been seen as an important source for investment which indirectly influences the economic growth. However, some past literature has shown that higher savings was due to higher economic growth. Therefore, this study aims to examine the causal relationship between savings and economic growth in Malaysia by using Granger causality test. The empirical analysis is based on time series data for 30 years from 1978 to 2007. The findings reveal that savings granger causes economic growth and not vice versa. Therefore, policies that encourage savings should be designated so as to enhance the economic growth in Malaysia. The availability of a wide range of savings instruments for savers and easily accessible instrument, for example, is a necessary condition for effective mobilization of the nation's savings. In future research, the ongoing evolution of an innovative, dynamic and diversified financial system in Malaysia is necessary so as to always encourage Malaysian people to save and invest for their future.
WIDER Working Paper
Resource mobilization continues to be an important policy challenge for developing economies, raising questions as to what determines differences in saving behaviour across countries. Using a panel of 47 economies with at least 40 years of continuous time series data, we causally identify, using a range of approaches, that higher productivity growth leads to greater savings, thereby contributing to higher investment. The dynamics of such productivity shocks have been disentangled into trend and cyclical shocks to uncover that cyclical productivity shocks tend to have a strong positive effect on saving rates. Comparing two countries with different levels of productivity (high and low) in a counterfactual analysis, this result remains robust, and we reconfirm that large declines in productivity shocks were associated with large decline in saving rates. Countries should focus on promoting policies to boost productivity growth and thereby achieve higher savings instead of focusing on sa...
2012
This paper examines the role of saving in accelerating economic growth in Bangladesh and estimates a simultaneous equation related to this to assess the impact of various factors in determining savings and economic growth in Bangladesh with special emphasis on the impact of financial sector reforms initiated in the late 1980s. The findings reveal that the growth rate and real rate of interest have a positive impact on saving rate. Also the dummy variable (financial reform index) has a significant positive effect on saving rate indicating that the financial sector reform has ultimately enhanced saving rate in Bangladesh. Population per branch of scheduled banks, on the other hand, is negatively related to saving rate suggesting that increased availability of branches of banks can stimulate the saving tendency of people. Further, financial savings in turn, foreign direct investment and literacy rate positively affect the growth rate of the economy. Our findings also confirm the saving-growth simultaneity reflecting that saving and growth positively affect each other and go hand to hand.
This study attempts to examine the nexus between domestic saving and economic growth in Nigeria from 1981 to 2018. The study employed annual time series data from the Central Bank of Nigeria's statistical bulletin. The variables understudy (domestic saving, government capital formation, inflation, interest rate and economic growth) were subjected to stationarity test using Augmented Dickey Fuller test (ADF). Johansen co-integration test was employed to test for long-run equilibrium relationship among the variables. While Vector error correction model was employed for the analyses of short run dynamic relationship among the variables. The ADF test revealed that all the variables are stationary at first difference. The Johansen co-integration test reveals long-run equilibrium relationship among the variables. Also, the long-run co-integrating vector result is similar to the dynamic short-run vector error correction model result. Findings reveal that domestic saving and inflation have negative relationship with economic growth while interest rate and government capital formation have positive relationship with economic growth. The error correction term is-0.010370. The study recommended that government should encourage production of goods and services because increase in the output level can reduce inflation to the required minimum level. Government should embark on suitable interest rate policies that will augment the economy. Government capital formation should be encouraged as it translates to investments that are capable of boosting the economy.
Journal of International Business and Economics, 2014
Achieving a high and stable economic growth rate is an important issue for every country since economic growth is crucial for economic development. Since savings is key to economic growth, this paper assesses the relationship between savings and total and non-oil economic growth for Iran. We also analyze the long-run causality among the above variables in Iran's economy. Annual data for the period 1972-2010 is used with an Autoregressive Distributed Lag Model for the empirical results. The resultsof the study show that there is a positive and significant impact of savings on total and non-oil economic growth. Both types of economic growth are also found to have positive and significant effect on savings. In addition, the results show that there is a long-run causal relationship between savings and economic growth, and between saving and non-oil economic growth, and that these relations are two-way.
2000
This paper provides a descriptive analysis of the long-and short-run correlations among saving, investment, and growth rates for 123 countries over the period 1961-94. Three results are robust across data sets and estimation methods: i) lagges saving rates are positively related to investment rates; ii) investment rates Granger cause growth rates with a negative sign; iii) growth rates Granger-cause investment with a positive sign.
1997
The main aim of this paper is to provide an exhaustive and careful descriptive analysis of the correlations among saving, investment and growth rates. We want to establish what are the main (aggregate)'stylized facts' that link these variables. For such a purpose we use new data set, gathered by the World Bank, containing a wide range of variables for 150 countries over the post WWII period. The data set is probably the best panel of countries available to date.
2015
It is often argued that policies that support national savings are critical to economic growth of countries. It is believed that the level of savings in any country should be of major concern to stakeholders. This study uses a Generalized Least Squares (GLS) panel regression technique to examine the impact of savings on economic growth. The study further examines the effect both openness and level of development have on the impact of savings on economic growth with the aid of interaction terms. The study finds that savings have both direct and indirect impact on economic growth. The indirect effect occurs through the impact of investments in human and physical capital on economic growth. The study also finds that both higher capital mobility (financial openness) and higher levels of development lower the impact of national savings on economic growth.
2014
Savings is known as a major factor in the economic development (Najafi, Ghorbani, 1998, p.48). Economists have always realized the importance of savings in the economic development (Komayjani, Rahmani, 1993, p.3). Each country needs investment to achieve economic growth; the necessary condition for investment is savings. (Mojtahed and Karami, 2003, p. 3). One of the problems in the economy of Iran and developing countries is the low rate of savings, and so the weak growth of investment. Thus, capital is considered as the main scarce factor in these countries. Hence, capital accumulation for economic growth and development of these countries is of great importance (Permeh, 2004,p.170). The purpose of this study, is to study the effect of growth rate of real GDP per capita on the savings rate in twelve (12) developing countries, (Islamic Republic of Iran, Botswana, the Dominican Republic, Zimbabwe, Niger, Burundi, Burkina Faso, Central African Republic, Rwanda, Togo, Nepal, Benin) and seven (7) developed countries (United States of America, Iceland, Luxembourg, Norway, Singapore, Greece, United kingdom). Data analysis as panel data with annual data from 1965 to 2010 is expressed in eviews7 and stata11 software. The results show the positive effects of the lags saving rate and the growth rate of real per capita GDP on the savings rate. The results are statistically significant. Also,The results show that the structure between the two groups (developed and developing countries) is different. Effectiveness rate and the growth rate of real GDP per capita on the savings rate in developed countries is lower than in developing countries.
African Development Review, 2001
This paper utilizes cointegration and the vector errorcorrection model (VECM) to explore the causal relationship between economic growth and growth rate of domestic savings for Congo, Côte d'Ivoire, Ghana, Kenya, South Africa, and Zambia. Specifically, three analyses were undertaken. First, the time series properties of economic growth and domestic savings were ascertained with the help of the augmented Dickey-Fuller unit root procedure. Second, the long-run relationship between economic growth and growth rate of domestic savings was examined in the context of the Johansen and Juselius (1990) framework. Finally, a Granger-causality test was undertaken to determine the direction of causality between economic growth and growth rate of domestic savings. The results indicate one order of integration [I(1)] for each of the series. The results of the cointegration tests suggest that there is a long-run relationship between economic growth and growth rate of savings. The results from the Grangercausality tests indicate that contrary to the conventional wisdom, economic growth prima facie causes growth rate of domestic savings for most of the countries under consideration. Résumé: Le présent document utilise la co-intégration et le modèle à vecteur de correction des erreurs (VECM) pour étudier les relations de cause à effet entre la croissance économique et les taux de croissance de l'épargne intérieure au Congo, en Côte d'Ivoire, au Ghana, au Kenya, en Afrique du Sud et en Zambie. Plus précisément, trois analyses ont été effectuées. La première a vérifié les propriétés des séries chronologiques de la croissance économique et de l'épargne intérieure à l'aide de la méthode Dickey-Fuller de racine unitaire augmentée. La deuxième a examiné les relations à long terme entre la croissance économique et les taux de croissance de l'épargne intérieure
Journal of economics and sustainable development, 2011
This study discusses the trend in Nigerian saving behaviour and reviews policy options to increase domestic saving. It also examines the determinants of private saving in Nigeria during the period covering 1970 – 2007. It makes an important contribution to the literature by evaluating the magnitude and direction of the effects of the following key policy and non-policy variables on private saving: Income growth, interest rate, fiscal policy, and financial development. The framework for analysis involves the estimation of a saving rate function derived from the Life Cycle Hypothesis while taking into cognizance the structural characteristics of a developing economy. The study employs the Error-Correction modelling procedure which minimizes the possibility of estimating spurious relations, while at the same time retaining long-run information. The results of the analysis show that the saving rate rises with both the growth rate of disposable income and the real interest rate on bank d...
Central Bank Review, 2015
Standard neoclassical growth models assume that foreign savings are perfect substitutes of domestic savings in financing domestic capital. Therefore, domestic saving rates are supposed to have no impact on investments and growth rates of countries. However, these models fail to explain the divergence of growth rates between East Asian countries with high domestic saving rates and other emerging market economies with low saving rates. This study forwards the view that saving-investment gaps, if not domestic savings themselves, may explain to some extent the divergence of growth rates among countries. We borrow the methodology of Aizenman et al. (2007) in calculating self-financing ratios (cumulative saving-investment gaps) of 46 countries for the period of 1993-2010. Surprisingly, we find that countries on average financed a larger fraction of their capital by domestic savings in the 2000s when international financial integration has intensified and there has been a surge in capital ...
Recent empirical work on the strength of precautionary saving has yielded widely varying conclusions. The mixed findings may reflect a number of difficulties in proxying uncertainty, executing instrumental variables estimation, and incorporating theoretical restrictions into empirical models. For each of these problems, this paper uses existing bestpractice techniques and some new strategies to relate unemployment probabilities from the Current Population Survey to net worth data from the Survey of Consumer Finances. We find that increases in unemployment risk do not boost saving by households with relatively low permanent income, but that a statistically significant precautionary effect emerges for households at a moderate level of income. This finding is robust to certain restrictions on the sample, but not robust across measures of wealth: We generally find a significant precautionary motive in broad measures of wealth that include home equity, but not in narrower subaggregates comprising only financial assets and liabilities.
Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development, 2022
The purpose of this research is to inves-tigate the dynamic interaction between savings, investment and economic growth in a case of Ethiopia by using quarterly time series data of National Bank of Ethiopia (NBE) from the periods 1992/93 to 2019/20. Consequently, the Vector Error Correction Model (VECM) results showed that there was a positive long run relationship between savings, investment and economic growth in Ethiopia. Granger causality from domestic invest-ment and real GDP to domestic savings and domestic investment granger causes economic growth. The response of do-mestic investment to a positive shock of real GDP is positive. Investment and money supply reacts positively to shocks of domestic saving. Whereas, the ex-change rate responds adversely to the shock of investment. In the short run the reaction of saving to shocks of real GDP and investment was positive and negative respectively. Whereas, shocks of saving generate a negative effect in the short run and insignificant effect on economic growth in the long run. Real GDP re-sponds negatively to shocks of interest rate and exchange rate. Besides, the var-iance decomposition results show that the variation of economic growth is largely explained by shocks to itself and in-vestment. The variation in saving ema-nates from the money supply, domestic savings, real GDP and investment. In-vestment deviation is also emanating from Real GDP and saving. Thus, the govern-ment and stakeholders are supposed to practice macroeconomic policies that will promote economic growth and gross domestic investment and thus saving will increase.
Loading Preview
Sorry, preview is currently unavailable. You can download the paper by clicking the button above.