Academia.edu no longer supports Internet Explorer.
To browse Academia.edu and the wider internet faster and more securely, please take a few seconds to upgrade your browser.
In an October 2009 Urban Studies article, Dick Carpenter and John Ross present new research on eminent domain in the US. The authors study areas where local governments plan to acquire property via eminent domain and convey that property to other private owners. They show that area residents are disproportionately members of ''less politically powerful populations'' and situate their findings within critical urban theory. This response argues that, although Carpenter and Ross do make a useful empirical contribution to the literature, there is an unacknowledged dissonance between their theoretical and normative frameworks and those of most critical urban theorists. The latter understand redevelopment within the broader context of neo-liberalism and structural inequality, and advocate equitable and communitycontrolled redevelopment. While Carpenter and Ross' position on neo-liberalism and community control is unclear, they are affiliated with an organisation that prioritises individual property rights rather than equity.
St. John's Law Review, 2006
If eminent domain is to serve true community development, statutory reforms must limit its propensity to abuse while still preserving its effectiveness. The first part of this article offers a normative legal theory of eminent domain as constrained by both the availability of alternative means of achieving public objectives and the inability of some condemnees to be made whole by cash compensation. The consideration of the land needs of both the condemnor and the condemnee is crucial to the respective evaluations of "public use" and "just compensation" as limitations on eminent domain. In the context of urban redevelopment, the theory supports greater resident autonomy in the compulsory assembly of residential land to subsidize and induce private economic development. The article's second part articulates two legislative reforms that protect residents from unjustified, irreparable harm without depriving urban redevelopment of eminent domain's essential efficacy in coordinating investment. Specifically, homeowners should not be subject to eminent domain pursuant to a redevelopment plan until the majority of them have approved the plan. To further solidify resident ownership of redevelopment, the right to continued residency in the community should be protected by amending relocation laws to guarantee an alienable entitlement to be offered replacement housing in the redeveloped district area. Together, these two legislative reforms express a more nuanced balance of property and liability rules that will facilitate a more productive interface between community residents and redevelopment officials.
International Journal of Social Science Studies, 2018
The article analyses the transformations of the use of eminent domain in the United States in the context of urban redevelopment programs. In the past the private property has been expropriated for public use only. Recently it is possible to forcibly transfer property, from a private subject to private developers, on the basis of a cost-benefit analysis that demonstrates that the new use is more efficient than the previous one. This profound change has been possible thanks to a progressive modification of the concept of public use. Traditionally, public use coincided with the construction of infrastructures and public utility, such as highways and railroads. Over the time, it has come to include other aims: firstly, projects of urban renewal and economic development carried forth by private developers. Essentially, it has resulted in the use of expropriation to assemble lands which are then granted to subjects who intervene in the reconfiguration of the city for private purposes. St...
Large-scale urban redevelopment projects catalyze moments of peril and opportunity.
Western New England Law Review, 2006
This article examines recent plans for US municipalities to use the state legal power of eminent domain to forcibly acquire ''underwater'' mortgages (i.e. those with negative equity), and to refinance them on terms more favorable to the homeowners in question, as a way of addressing in a socially progressive way the nation's ongoing foreclosure crisis. The article makes three main arguments. The first is that insofar as the plan threatens to disrupt prevailing norms of value distribution and risk bearing, it represents a fundamental challenge to the existing political economy of urban financial capitalism in the US and the law's mediation thereof. The second is that value, risk, and their mediation through law must be understood in the context of geographical unevenness and shifting scales of legal governance. The third is that the geographical political economy associated with the eminent domain plan is about discourses—of risk, of markets, and indeed of law per se—no less than materialities; and that the two are indelibly linked, with discourses having material effects when, through law, they structure value and risk for the manifold actors who operate within the sphere of housing finance.
HAL (Le Centre pour la Communication Scientifique Directe), 2019
Mots-clés : working-class neighborhood | working classes | urban renewal | urban policy | capitalism | neoliberalism | demolition | Department of Housing and Urban Development | HOPE VI program By allowing demolitions and evictions in well-located working-class neighborhoods, urban renewal is sometimes described as a neoliberal policy, favorable to land and property investors. But this interpretation, founded on the trauma of postwar urban policies, only tells part of the story when it comes to understanding contemporary urban renewal in the United States. The policy of urban renewal implemented in the United States in the 1950s and 1960s came to symbolize the collusion of local urban and economic elites within "growth coalitions" formed to control urban space and maximize its profitability (Logan and Molotch 1987). Municipalities had made excessive use of their eminent domain powers, leading to the expulsion of a million people-mostly African Americans-who were often relocated in public housing projects confined to the most segregated areas of cities. The land "released" by these operations was sold off to private investors or public institutions (universities, hospitals, etc.) in search of available land in or near business districts. With the launch of the federal HOPE VI (Housing Opportunities for People Everywhere) program, a new cycle of urban renewal began in the early 1990s and ended in the late 2000s. The aim was no longer to eliminate urban blight, defined extensively in urban-renewal policy, but rather to initiate a fundamental transformation of public housing, one of the assisted housing programs under the responsibility of the United States Department of Housing and Urban Development (HUD) and managed locally by public housing authorities. By an ironic twist of history, HOPE VI has sought to erase the most visible signs of modernist architecture-the towers and slab blocks-built to relocate the victims of the first urban renovation, [1] by replacing them with single-family houses designed to recreate the atmosphere of urban villages [2] that previous urban-renewal operations had precisely destroyed a few decades earlier. But while postwar urban renewal aimed to stem the economic decline of urban centers and the flight of the white middle classes to the residential suburbs, HOPE VI has taken place in a context of economic and demographic growth that has benefited central cities. Critical urban sociology saw this program as a tool to support the gentrification dynamics that began in the 1970s in certain urban centers (see, for example: Wyly and Hammel 1999; Newman and Ashton 2004; Hackworth 2007). HOPE VI was viewed as a key element in the attractiveness strategies of "entrepreneurial cities," facilitating the development of a real-estate offer dedicated to the middle and upper social categories, which, in the ongoing fight to control space, would force poor minorities to increasingly exile themselves to the urban periphery. By actively promoting local public-private partnerships, the federal government was supposed to trigger a dynamic of investment in social-housing neighborhoods that had hitherto been neglected by the commercial sector, despite their central locations, as the initial public-sector investment would be more than matched by private capital ready to be used as a result of the globalization of financial markets. [3] Such an interpretation has been strongly relativized in the context of European and French cities. Contemporary urban policies inherit the specificity of national contexts, as well as the histories, social relations and modes of regulation specific to each city, resulting in contrasting translations of the entrepreneurial city model. Thus, urban housing strategies are not only oriented towards an objective of residential attractiveness encouraging the gentrification of popular spaces, but also aim to maintain the original inhabitants or create the conditions for a social mix (Le Galès 2003; Morel Journel and Sala Pala 2011). This relativization also applies, albeit to a lesser extent, to the United States, which is often presented as the Trojan horse of a neoliberalization of urban policies. [4] The analysis of contemporary urban renewal must also Urban Renewal in the USA: A Neoliberal Policy?-Metropolitics https://www.metropolitiques.eu/spip.php?page=print&id_article...
2002
One of a city's greatest assets is its available land for development. Unfortunately, many cities have land and properties that are vacant, abandoned, or under-used, with few policies and regulations in place to convert them into revenue-generating, valuable sites. This brief outlines the ten recommended action steps that state and local governments might follow to facilitate the development of urban land and buildings. Compiling an inventory of vacant parcels, planning for the assembly and reuse of land, and working to eliminate the many legal and administrative barriers to acquisition and development are just some of the actions the authors contend should be undertaken in order to create a more transparent, efficient, and effective system for private market land development. The brief will discuss these and other proposed steps, and will highlight examples of successful practices implemented in states and localities throughout the U.S. resurgence of development for commercial, entertainment and residential uses. To capture and build upon this momentum, however, cities and older suburbs need to overcome a number of competitive disadvantages-poorly performing schools, aging infrastructure-while capitalizing upon their unique assets. This paper focuses on one of those assets-vacant and underutilized land and buildings-and provides an action agenda for urban leaders that can improve their capacity to market land, encourage development, and make the city a choice location for residents and businesses. Opportunities and Challenges V acant and abandoned urban properties are often viewed only as liabilities, and have seldom been counted among a city's assets. In fact, even efforts to quantify the extent of vacant land in cities have been few and far between. 5 The most recent, comprehensive attempt to understand how cities inventory and track these sites was a 1999 survey completed by Michael Pagano and Ann O'M. Bowman. Eighty-three cities with populations over 100,000 provided estimates of the number of abandoned structures and/or acres of "usable vacant land" within their boundaries. Survey results revealed that several cities, particularly Baltimore and Philadelphia, have large numbers of abandoned structures. In addition, the survey indicated that the average city possesses over 12,000 acres (or 15 percent of its area) of usable vacant land. 6 To put this amount of land in perspective, this average of 15 percent means that the 100 largest cities in the nation have the equivalent of the total combined land area of New York City, Los Angeles, Chicago, Houston, Philadelphia, and San Diego sitting idle. Not only do these vacant properties provide an opportunity for urban revitalization, but they offer an alternative source of developable land to green space at the edges of our metropolitan areas. The amount of usable vacant land varies widely among cities depending upon the nature and intensity of market forces working at many levels-from the conditions in the region, down to individual city blocks. San Francisco and Seattle, for example, are 'hot-market' cities located in very strong-market regions. They have far fewer vacant and abandoned properties than a city like Buffalo, located in an area of New York State that is suffering from a long-term economic readjustment and a loss of business and population. In virtually all cities, market conditions can vary substantially across neighborhoods. Historic circumstances, housing values, racial patterns, school quality, crime rates, and other variables account for these differences. Absent a robust real estate market, redeveloping vacant properties becomes a significant challenge for urban governments. Moreover, the overall neighborhood conditions resulting from decline-high crime, poor schools, lack of amenities-can cause further abandonment. In many cities and older suburbs, the scattered nature of land availability, the cost of assembly, and the public actions sometimes needed to assemble parcels make it virtually impossible for the private real estate sector to carryout larger-scale development. These impediments frequently frustrate market forces and divert development to where it is easier-on vacant undeveloped land, often located at the suburban fringe. The ability of cities to effectively carry out this often complex municipal function-vacant land redevelopment-varies widely from city to city, and can change within a city based on the internal capabilities of the local government. Part of the challenge for local governments is to overcome the many legal and administrative barriers to the reuse of urban land. Often, tracts of land in cities are not readily available-they are owned by numerous parties, entangled in cumbersome property tax foreclosure laws, improperly zoned for reuse, require infrastructure to be removed or modernized, or require environmental remediation. Real estate developers often complain of a lack of planning and coordination between government departments and developers, inconsistent and slow permitting and inspection processes, and delays by local governments on subsidy commitments-all factors that discourage private development. In order for local leaders to respond to market demands, and catalyze neighborhood revitalization, they must implement an effective process for reclaiming urban properties.
2016
Ultimately, Somin’s single-minded dedication to a federal constitutional ban on economic development taking prevents the book from offering a full and fair consideration of alternative responses to eminent domain abuse. His survey of the various state legislative reforms enacted as a result of homeowner backlash to Kelo quite rightly points out the shortcomings of populist challenges to sophisticated vested interests. But his blatant aversion to engage with the substantial problems that public purpose land assembly faces without resort to eminent domain closes off any fair comparison of proposals that rival his own, particularly the position of fellow libertarian and ardent Kelo critic, Richard Epstein. Even so, the failure of Somin’s ambitious argument does not prevent the book from being an informative, engaging, and timely contribution to this fascinating and chronically misunderstood subject
Venezuela, among other countries, they are being used as instruments for the expansion of rights to the city and the construction of the just city.
2019
Upstate New York has historically faced economic hardships, and the cities within the region have struggled to cope with population loss, urban flight, and decaying buildings. In response, the cities of Albany, Buffalo, Niagara Falls, Rochester, Syracuse, and Utica have set up urban renewal agencies in order to combat this issue. Through various methods of urban renewal, including land disposition and eminent domain, these cities have created disasters for the residents of the cities and the character of the environment during the period of heavy American urban renewal in the mid-20 th century. Since this time, the urban renewal agencies have drifted from each other in terms of the strategies that they employ for renewal. Many cities currently utilize methods of acquiring properties and reselling them to developers. This strategy has resulted in higher quality housing, but has not necessarily provided greater quantities of housing. In contrast, the cities of Buffalo and Niagara Falls encourage larger scale developments by holding onto municipal properties until the proper buyer comes along, and redeveloping zoning regulations to make development easier. Urban renewal continues to serve an active role in political and economic issues throughout the Upstate New York region, as well as the nation as a whole. iii Table of Contents List of Tables iii List of Figures iv Chapter 1: Background 1.1 The Rise and Fall of Upstate New York 1.2 The Introduction of Urban Renewal
Several US counties and local governments have recently considered a novel solution to the foreclosure crisis. They plan to use eminent domain to compel the owners of mortgage debt––and specifically of private-label mortgage-backed securities––to sell the debt to the government at a price reflecting the loan's market value. The government would then restructure the debt and resell it to new investors. The plans are striking because–– in contrast to both development-driven eminent domain and the federal subprime bank bailout––they would force investors to assume asset devaluation and increased long-term risk. Notably, the plans have emerged as an instance of financialization-focused politics in suburbs and suburban cities of color, specifically majority-black and-Latino/a suburbs. Local support for the plans, we argue, is rooted in the long-term disinvestment of these 'suburbs of exception', which became targets of subprime lending and eventually sites where the 'financial exception' has been localized. But these demographic shifts, fragmentation and fiscal pressures have at the same time created a suburban political terrain in which the plans have gained their strongest political support.
Equity is a crucial goal of American urban policy. The means by which it is pursued via the liberal approach to urban policy-augmented redistributionis problematic, however. What is needed, therefore, is an alternative means to advance equity. Broadening ownership (of productive assets) can be the basis of such an alternative. I discuss how the liberal approach to American urban policy can be transcended by supplanting its Redistributive Paradigm with an Ownership Paradigm.
Public housing reform has fostered widespread revitalization in American cities. Courts have been critical to this process, but so far urban scholars have not yet closely analyzed this role. This article illuminates how courts participated in reform, sometimes empowering and at other times disempowering tenants. Looking at litigation filed by tenants to fight demolition, I examine how courts framed disputes in legal terms and how the judicial stance on demolition coevolved with national policy debate. In particular, I emphasize how tenants tapped into the ideological power of rights in American society and show that courts never explicitly rejected the notion that tenants held rights against demolition but instead gradually adopted urban planning sensibilities that implicitly denied rights to tenants. Thus, this article reveals the complicated and paradoxical nature of legal rights in the Right to the City struggles.
Journal of Urban Affairs, 1994
This study examines the conflict between inner city property owners and lower income tenants for control of neighborhood development agendas and community-based organizations. Utilizing a case study of Minneapolis and St. Paul, the authors investigated neighborhood conflicts over community revitalization. In a number of neighborhoods in the two cities, the community organization has come to be dominated by property owners espousing an "ideology of property" hostile to ajfordable housing. This has led to tension and conflict between neighborhood organizations pursuing owner interests and community development corporations focusing on low income housing.
Journal of the American Planning Association, 2019
This dissertation contributes to the literatures on post-2007 urban governance and urban greening by drawing novel connections between vacant land reuse, including urban agriculture, and the structures of urban governance. Through a historical analysis of housing vacancy, an institutional analysis of Cleveland’s community development industry’s response to the 2008 foreclosure crisis, and a case study of a vacant land reuse project, I argue that Cleveland’s community development industry shifted towards vacant land reuse and intervention to stabilize property values in response to the foreclosure crisis. This shift reveals a temporary resolution of the failure of subsidized housing construction following the crisis, but does not represent a significant departure from neoliberal community development. While the City has been effective in fostering certain forms of reuse, the heavy involvement of the community development industry and community foundations, combined with a local government facing fiscal pressure, has resulted in a constrained political field of opportunity for vacant land reuse. By devolving the labor of lot maintenance onto residents and continuing to prioritize traditional economic development, many of the possibilities for using vacant land reuse for social and environmental justice have been limited. However, I also show that the incorporation of vacant land reuse within the community development industry in Cleveland was the outcome of a process of weak contestation, negotiation, and path dependency, not a simple imposition of neoliberal ideology. Additionally, my findings concerning reuse projects on the ground reveals the shortcomings of relying on under-resourced resident labor and shows cracks in the hegemony of private property and market logics in high-abandonment neighborhoods. My findings point to the importance of studying how greening projects are interacting with preexisting structures of urban governance. It suggests that the commodification of land and market-based community development places limits on vacant land reuse that directly benefits residents and works towards environmental and food justice.
2014
Land Use Policy, 2019
In recent decades, many states have considerably reduced their involvement in providing vital public services such as housing. This trend, manifested inter alia in the growing reliance on private initiatives, is redefining the state's responsibility to delineate and protect the land rights of various individuals and groups. In this paper we propose a new typology of land rights, which relates not only to the conventional rights but also to rights derived from public and political arrangements that are usually taken into account in practice but are not yet in literature. Using the theoretical typology we developed, this study examines and compares the land rights trajectories of two adjacent neighborhoods in Tel-Aviv, Israel. The research findings conceptualize the role of the state in defining and protecting property rights of urban residents under two scenarios: when land is nationally owned and when it has become privately owned. Moreover, the findings demonstrate the influence of different types of land rights on the range of opportunities available to urban residents and emphasize the increased need for clearly defined property rights in the neoliberal era, especially for disadvantaged populations. ladder between two extremes: full property rights (rung 1) and no rights (rung 7). Using this theoretical typology, this study examines and compares the land rights trajectories of two groups of urban residents. Since the mid-1980s, influenced by the waves of neoliberalism that have swept the globe, many societies have reduced the government's role-through privatization, deregulation, and cuts in public ex
Loading Preview
Sorry, preview is currently unavailable. You can download the paper by clicking the button above.