Academia.edu no longer supports Internet Explorer.
To browse Academia.edu and the wider internet faster and more securely, please take a few seconds to upgrade your browser.
2017, The Rise of Populism: Lessons for the European Union and the United States of America
AI
The paper examines the interplay between neoliberalism, austerity, and economic populism, particularly in light of the economic crises since 2007. It highlights how, despite ostensibly correct economic policies, many countries have faced budget deficits, external debts, and stagnation, raising questions about the validity and implications of these approaches compared to traditional economic populism. The focus is on the political ramifications of poor economic performance and the public's search for alternatives, even at the risk of undermining democratic values.
The notion of both 'ideology' and 'science' are numerous, contentious and sometimes contradictory depending on different authors' cognitive vantage points with its own sociohistoric genesis. This paper seeks to critically evaluate Joseph Schumpeter's view on relationship between 'ideology' and 'science' and its mutual interdependence in generating knowledge in social sciences like economics. In economics his analysis is much more broad and contextual than his other contemporaries. His view of 'Ideology' as "pre-analytic vision about real world economic events conditioned by social-historic positioning of social agent/theorist" and 'science' as "mere box of analytic tools continually evolving and getting perfected" and former being continuously subjected to critical assessment of later, is evaluated from the soundness of its epistemological and ontological standpoint. Borrowing from different schools of philosophy (Marxist, Critical Realist, and Philosophy of Science), Schumpeter's construction on 'ideology' and 'science' is critically evaluated.
Scandinavian Economic History Review, 2022
This article analyses late 1960s’ and early 1970s’ policy debate on issues concerning balance of payments in Sweden. Part of this debate was the question of fiscal austerity as a tool to achieve external balance, and if it could be used without risking economic and social unrest. The aim is twofold: first to empirically shine new light on modern Swedish economic policy in a historic context. Second to theoretically explore new ways of interpreting the relationship between political thinking and economic ideas. Special focus within the second aim are the consequences of political thinking on Keynesian economic ideas as a framework of economic understanding at the time. The study is qualitative in its methods and pays attention to limits within the relationship between economic policymaking and economic expertise. The article highlights conflicting perspectives on Keynesian ideas and the heterogeneity of these perspectives among economic experts. A heterogeneity of this kind is also shown to complicate the assumed close relationship between Social Democracy and Keynesianism in a historic context. In essence, the article shows that studying policy debates in close historic detail makes for new conclusions on the development of modern economic ideas and the part political thinking plays in it.
The paper reviews the basis for claims by anti-economists, over history and from both conservative and radical perspectives, that economics cannot be fully purged of ideological elements and to that extent cannot be scientific. The paper first distinguishes five versions of this thesis, and then refutes them one by one. Tables are ultimately turned: the best scientific economics is argued to be exemplary anti-ideology.
The assessment of the current status of economics must take into consideration the intellectual and historical context. Such an approach enables the understanding of the causal relationship between the evolution of economic ideas and theories and the major financial and economic crises. The current impasse of economics is caused by the inability of the dominant theory to identify the forces that contribute to the destabilization of the economic system and to provide adequate solutions. Economic crises are essentially crisis of ideas. The impact of the orthodox economic theory on the global crisis is indisputable and requires considerable theoretical and methodological efforts to reform the economy. Change of vision, openness to a non-conformist thinking, realistic and practical approaches represent fundamental dimensions of a deeply humanistic economic science.
2012
There is not just one economic theory but a number of competing theories. The dominant theory is the neoclassical theory. This theory describes the economic system as a self-regulating system, with a unique and stable equilibrium characterised by full employment, the absence of crisis and uncertainty, and with an objective and fair distribution of income. To cope with the evidence to the contrary, the neoclassical theory built up a highly sophisticated protective belt of auxiliary hypotheses. There is, however, no change in the economic policy recipe: laissez faire! Even before the neoclassical theory came into being, Ricardo and Marx showed that the economic or rather capitalist system is instead characterised by distributive conflict and that crises are the norm within it. Moreover, the critiques developed by Keynes and Sraffa during the twentieth century have shown that the world we live in is fraught with uncertainty, that the neoclassical theory is vitiated by irreparable logical flaws, and that if economic theory is to arrive at relevant conclusions, the importance of the political and ideological dimension – of history – must be recognised.
HISTORY OF ECONOMIC THOUGHT AND POLICY, 2013
for their help in discussing and revising the text. 1 It further implies that the problem might be only a matter of communication failure, as Rees (1986: 138) suggests: "economists do a very bad job of communicating the principles on which [they] agree". 2 At the workshop, other papers were presented. Among them, Francesco Cattabrini's paper on Copyright © FrancoAngeli N.B: Copia ad uso personale. È vietata la riproduzione (totale o parziale) dell'opera con qualsiasi mezzo effettuata e la sua messa a disposizione di terzi, sia in forma gratuita sia a pagamento. Copyright © FrancoAngeli N.B: Copia ad uso personale. È vietata la riproduzione (totale o parziale) dell'opera con qualsiasi mezzo effettuata e la sua messa a disposizione di terzi, sia in forma gratuita sia a pagamento.
Revue De Philosophie Economique, 2005
2010
Una nueva estrategia liberal. La filosofía pragmatista. La matemática axiomática. Mercado y teoría de juegos. Sobre el cálculo del bienestar. El equilibrio general. Modelar expectativas. Bibliografía
1983
The paper analyzes consensus and dissension among economists on the basis of surveys conducted in Belgium, France, Germany, Switzerland and the United States. The outcome of the analysis is that there exists a considerable amount of consensus, but substantial differences across countries. In Europe, and especially in Belgium and France, the views of 'left' and 'right' economists differ; these differences are strong, as expected, on propositions which have a clear ideological content. However, it also appears that economists are not always willing to distinguish 'technical' and 'political' apects of an economic issue.
History of Political Economy, 2007
The Palgrave Handbook of Populism, 2022
Popular among economists, pundits and policymakers, the theory of economic populism is used to criticize expansionist policies purportedly enacted by fiscally irresponsible populist governments. Introduced by Jeffrey Sachs, Rüdiger Dornbusch and Sebastian Edwards in 1989, the theory maintains that such policies put into motion a cycle of economic devastation where populists register initial successes but soon face bottlenecks and other market failures that lead to hyperinflation and balance-of-payments problems, ending with regime change and the restoration of orthodox policies. On their part, political scientists have strongly resisted economically deterministic interpretations of populism, submitting adequate evidence that populist phenomena are not associated with particular economic policies. However, the popularity of economic populism remains intact. This article opens a new and expanded line of criticism by exposing the normative historical foundations of the theory of economic populism, while highlighting an array of conceptual, methodological and empirical flaws that render it unfit for scientific purposes. The insistence on its use despite obvious analytical shortcomings is explained as an artifact of economic populism’s ideologically weaponized nature.
2018
This paper traces the ascent of liberal economic ideas in the macroeconomic establishment in Denmark from the 1970s to the 2000s. Based on a systematic analysis of documents from the Danish government and the Economic Council published between 1970 and 2004, this paper demonstrates that Denmark experienced a marked shift in paradigms during this period. Full employment Keynesianism dominated the 1970s and neoclassical liberalism became dominant from the late 1980s and early 1990s. The paper argues that the nature of this paradigm shift is more uneven and gradual than the literature traditionally suggests. Furthermore, the adoption of new strict monetary and fiscal policies was already in place from the early 1980s, before the intellectual tools of the new paradigm were dominant and developed. This suggests that it was not the intellectual dominance of liberal ideas that caused the initial adoption of neoliberal policies. It is argued instead that the central role of economic theory is rather in legitimating and justifying policy, and that the stability of economic strategy, despite changes in government, points towards a situation where neoclassical liberalism has taken the form of common sense in the policy elite. This may in turn restrain the scope of legitimate public debate and policy action.
2008
Course Description A comparison of capitalism, socialism and communism, emphasizing the ideas and ideologies that are struggling today across the world. Special attention will be given to selected European and American political, economic, and cultural theorists. In many ways, this course builds on GOVT 490, which focuses on the close reading of texts (Dialectic). This course continues in the same vein but also adds the last dimension of the Trivium, Rhetoric, in which the focus shifts to independent research, presentation, and writing as well as collaborative efforts that involve critical evaluation and the discussion of readings and papers. A more appropriate title for the course would be Ideas Have Consequences, the title of one of the founding works of American conservatism by Richard M. Weaver. II.
SOFT POWER – Euro-American Journal of Historical and Theoretical Studies of Politics and Law, Issue 11 ( 6,1) – January-June 2019, 2019
New Political Economy, 2008
The approaches and opinions of economists often dominate public policy discussion. Economists have gained this privileged position partly (or perhaps mainly) because of the obvious relevance of their subject matter, but also because of the unified methodology (neo-classical economics) that the vast majority of modern economists bring to their analysis of policy problems and proposed solutions. The idea of Pareto efficiency and its potential trade-off with equity is a central idea that is understood by all economists and this common language provides the economics profession with a powerful voice in public affairs. The purpose of this paper is to review and reflect upon the way in which economists find themselves analysing and providing suggestions for social improvements and how this role has changed over roughly the last 60 years. We focus on the fundamental split in the public economics tradition between those that adhere to public finance and those that adhere to public choice. A pure public finance perspective views failures in society as failures of the market. The solutions are technical, as might be enacted by a benevolent dictator. The pure public choice view accepts (sometimes grudgingly) that markets may fail, but so, it insists, does politics. This signals institutional reforms to constrain the potential for political failure. Certain policy recommendations may be viewed as compatible with both traditions, but other policy proposals will be the opposite of that proposed within the other tradition. In recent years a political economics synthesis emerged. This accepts that institutions are very important and governments require constraints, but that some degree of benevolence on the part of policy makers should not be assumed non-existent. The implications for public policy from this approach are, however, much less clear and perhaps more piecemeal. We also discuss analyses of systematic failure, not so much on the part of markets or politicians, but by voters. Most clearly this could lead to populism and relaxing the idea that voters necessarily choose their interests. The implications for public policy are addressed. Throughout the paper we will relate the discussion to the experience of UK government policy-making.
1992
This paper relates economic theorising and policy making in a context of people's changing behaviour, which makes economy to work in a different way. As economic theory is not adapting to these changes, it produces false predictions. Also institutional factors and their changes are not usually taken into account. Disagreements among economists play a vital role to this. They mainly arise from the existence of value judgements. Although usually exaggerated, disagreements can be minimised if value judgements are formed by using the whole set of the available information about the function and needs of the society. And this can be done only if economists can have a global view of the other social disciplines. * Many of the ideas developed here, can be also found in Vliamos, 1991. However, here they are developed in a different context.
Loading Preview
Sorry, preview is currently unavailable. You can download the paper by clicking the button above.