Academia.edu no longer supports Internet Explorer.
To browse Academia.edu and the wider internet faster and more securely, please take a few seconds to upgrade your browser.
2024, The European Journal of the History of Economic Thought
https://doi.org/10.1080/09672567.2024.2396856…
1 page
1 file
Owing to the mainstream interpretation of classical economics as being supply-side, studies examining the analytical role of demand and consumption have been scarce. In this paper, I bring together such passages in Cantillon, Steuart, Smith and Ricardo and forge an analytical link between social tastes and consumption— an attempt at reconstructing a classical theory of taste formation. A classical theory of taste formation has as its foundation methodological holism—viewing social classes as the fundamental unit of analysis. Through a discussion of necessaries and luxuries in the above classical economists, the social division of commodities is highlighted. By drawing on social classes and the social division of commodities, it is seen that taste plays a critical role in the determination of economic growth by influencing consumption expenditure. Finally, it is demonstrated that taste is both a cause and consequence of foreign trade.
International Review of Social History, 1995
Economic Anthropology , 2024
How are taste judgments made and shared? Drawing on fieldwork among Ceylon tea brokers and buyers, the industry’s de facto tea tasters, this article offers an ethnographic account of aesthetic judgment in practice. I ask, what makes a tea good? Tea tasters’ unanimous response amounted to a market relativism of sorts that shifted attention away from the tasted object: “It all depends on the market.” Following my informants’ contention, I show how industry actors are able to enact a tentative resolution to the fundamental paradox inherent in the judgment of taste, namely, its ostensibly subjective nature and simultaneous claim to objectivity. “The market,” invoked time and again by tea tasters, and imagined as inherently objective, affords the seamless translation of taste judgments into prices, intelligible and shareable quantities, prompting a reimagining of taste as an economic fact.
2001
The object of this paper is to show some examples of economies in which singular equilibria occur as a consequence of utility functions and where this equilibria play a crucial rolle to understand the behavior of the economy as a system. An economy will be called singular if little changes in the tastes of the consumer imply big changes in the equilibria set.
Revista Mexicana de Economía y Finanzas
The purpose of this paper is to show sorne examples, and characteristics of the economies where, as a consequence of changes in the utility functions, the set of equilibria changes. These changes play a crucial role to understand the behavior of the economy as a system. An economy will be called singular if small changes in the tastes of t he consumers imply big changes in the set of equilibria. In this paper, we use the Negishi (1960) approach to model the economic system composed by a finite number of agents and goods, to do so we use the concepts of Morse and stable functions to characterize the singular economies. Resumen El propósito de este trabajo es mostrar algunas características y ejemplos de las economías donde, a consecuencia de cambios en las funciones de utilidad, el conjunto de equilibrio cambia. Estos cambios juegan un papel crucial para entender el comportamiento de la economía como un sistema. Se dice que una economía es singular si pequeños cambios en las preferencias de los consumidores generan grandes cambios en el conjunto de equilibrio. En este t rabajo se utiliza la aproximación de Negishi (1960) para modelar un sistema económico con un número finito de agentes y bienes, para lo cual se utilizan los conceptos d e Morse y funciones estables con el fin de representar a las economías sing ulares.
The Anthem Companion to David Ricardo, 2023
The aims of this essay are twofold: (i) to understand Ricardo's economics in relation to other classical political economists, especially Smith, Sismondi, and Malthus and (ii) to provide an alternative conceptual architecture for better understanding contemporary societies. Thus, it serves as a companion in the above two ways. While the locus of discussion is Ricardo's explanation of relative prices and income distribution (value theory), this shall be complemented by a discussion of his approach to economics and his theory of economic growth. In Ricardo's index to the Principles, there are five entries on Malthus, 1 one entry on Sismondi, 2 and over 20 entries on Smith. Ricardo writes approvingly of Malthus for presenting "to the of "Political Economy" but notes that they have not grasped the principles of rent and therefore that of income distribution (Works, I, 5-6). 3 The essay is organized as follows. Section 2 highlights the role of value theory in Ricardo's political economy and for economics in general. Section 3 provides an overview of Ricardo's method. Section 4 outlines Ricardo's critical engagement with use value and exchange value. Section 5 discusses Ricardo's theory of value and distribution. Section 6 engages with Ricardo's growth theory and the role of demand therein. Section 7 offers a conclusion. 2. The Raison d'etre of Value Theory Before stating the raison d'etre of value theory, it is necessary to present the aims or "objects" of political economy as laid out by Smith. Political oeconomy, considered as a branch of the science of a statesman or legislator, proposes two distinct objects: first, to provide a plentiful revenue or subsistence for the people, or more properly to enable them to provide such a revenue or subsistence for themselves; and secondly, to supply the state or commonwealth with a revenue sufficient for the public services. It proposes to enrich both the people and the sovereign. (Smith 1776, IV.1). The discussion of the social surplus is found in all the classical political economists, including William Petty and Richard Cantillon. The "gross revenue" is comprised of wages, profits, and rents whereas the "net revenue" comprises profits and rents (Works, I, 347-8). In the Wealth of Nations, Smith had included in "neat revenue" the "subsistence" of the inhabitants (Smith 1776, II.ii.5) thereby rendering it a non-strictly surplus conception since by definition subsistence implies necessary or essential and surplus implies non-necessary or non-essential (see also Aspromourgos 2009, 163). However, it must be noted that the conception of subsistence in classical political economy is more cultural than biological. Ricardo makes this qualification in the third edition of the Principles: "more is generally allotted to the labourer under the name of wages, than the absolutely necessary expenses of production" (Works, I, 348n); this suggests that a part of wages may be treated as "net revenue". In any case, Ricardo's definition of "net revenue" is more conceptually coherent than Smith's (for a succinct discussion on this matter, see Aspromourgos 2015, 473). Since both the aggregate output and the social surplus are made up of heterogenous commodities, a coherent economic accounting requires the knowledge of their prices. If an economy produces commodities y1, y2 and y3, the aggregate output Y=p1y1+p2y2+p3y3 where p1, of taxation warrants a clear theoretical understanding of the social surplus, which in turn necessitates a coherent value/price theory (see also King 2013, 80). More generally, it may be stated that "the analysis of value and distribution" provides "the foundation for the analysis of accumulation" (Bharadwaj 1989, 2). 3. Ricardo's Method Ricardo's method of doing political economy can be clearly grasped from the following chapters: 'On Natural and Market Price' (Chapter VII), 'Value and Riches, their Distinctive Properties' (Chapter XX), and 'On Gross and Net Revenue' (Chapter XXVI). Of these, we have already briefly engaged with the third method-the surplus approach-in the previous section.
A Brief History of Economic Thought
The evolution of economic thought can be traced back from its beginnings in classical antiquity up to the present day. In this book, Professor Alessandro Roncaglia offers a clear, concise and updated version of his award-winning The Wealth of Ideas, studying the development of economic thought through perspectives and debates on the economy and society over time. With chapters on prominent economic theorists, including William Petty, Karl Marx, and John Maynard Keynes, as well as on other important figures and key debates of each period, Roncaglia critically evaluates the foundations of the marginalist-neoclassical (scarcity-utility) approach in comparison to the Classical-Keynes approach. A comprehensive guide to the history of economic thought, this book will be of value not only to undergraduate and postgraduate students studying economic thought but also to any readers desiring to study how economics has evolved up to the present day. alessandro roncaglia is Professor of Economics at Sapienza University of Rome. He is a member of the Accademia Nazionale dei Lincei, Editor of PSL Quarterly Review and Moneta e Credito, and was previously President of the Società Italiana degli Economisti. His numerous publications, translated into various languages, include The Wealth of Ideas, also published by Cambridge University Press (2005).
University of Chicago Press eBooks, 2000
Oxford Handbook of the Sociology of Consumption, 2018
This chapter reexamines foundational philosophical controversies about the meaning of taste and reflects on how tastes have been understood by sociologists. It argues these insights, while revealing the social patterning of tastes, have also obscured the extent to which tastes are bound up both with sensory experience and with the process of learning the management of the body and its responses to the world.. It concludes that, while the substantive weight of the sociological study of tastes has concerned itself with questions of the aesthetic and to the identification of different dispositions held by individuals and groups in relation to aesthetic judgment, there is value, in understanding contemporary cultures, to building up those accounts of taste which are more oriented to questions of the ascetic and to the role of restraint and training in the development and cultivation of tastes.
Social Thought and Research, 1990
If you are on the left, and especially if you are a Marxist, you are not supposed to be desirous-of sex, cars, or Cuisinarts. An austere life is recommended for the revolutionary, who is to be both lean and mean-sort of an ascetic Rambo. Those who accumulate goods beyond their basic needs are regarded with suspicion and often loathing. But what are basic needs? Remember that Marx, himself, said that human needs are infmitely expandable (Marx 1973/1844). And remember, too, that one central goal of Marx's revolution was to enable the proletariat to live like the bourgeoisie. Even so, consumption is still in bad odor on the left. Who in their right minds are not distressed by the fact that the publisher/financier Malcolm Forbes spent between $2-3 million for his Moroccan birthday party in 1989? The excesses of Donald Trump are legend, but he has his counterparts in Japan, England, West Germany, and Switzerland. There are greedy people all over the globe; it takes no effort to find them. It is easy to condemn consumption, not just because of what people do now, but because of its history. In the popular mind, Rome fell because a ruling class was more concerned with circuses than production. In the court cultures of early modern Europe, aristocratic men and women were encouraged to consume with style and grace. When consumption became excessive, it was linked to moral excess, causing the (often Puritanical) lower orders to look upon the unfolding spectacle of consumption with disgust. And, finally, consumption is seen as a feminine activity, and therefore one to be treated as frivolous and meaningless (Mukerji 1989, p. 1462). Marx viewed consumption negatively because it led to alienation among people. The more you consume, the less human you are. In a nicely paradoxical relationship, each act of consumption eats away at the soul. How? Marx explains, in his well-known discussion of commodity fetishism (Marx 1977/1896). In capitalist societies, workers sell their labor power, and produce commodities, over which they have no control, for exchange. Commodities, be they cars or refrigerators, appear to have intrinsic characteristics, such as weight, color, and size, and they also have a price. Prices are determined by market forces (supply and demand, the cost of labor and materials). Price determines what gets produced as well as how goods are distributed. Goods which bring a high price/profit will be produced, as opposed to those which might meet a greater social need. Prices determine who gets what. The wages paid to the men or women who sell their labor power, determine how much power people have, how much they can buy of the very goods they have produced. Thus, relationships between people are determined by the prices of commodities. Relationships between people-the flesh and blood that 46 Consumption and Marxist Class Theory gratification and even a sense of self worth, even if those on the left don't
The European Journal of the History of Economic Thought, 2009
Canonical Authors in Consumption Theory, 2017
Since Jean Baudrillard, many consumer researchers consider consumption to be universally relevant. In late modern societies, they tend to argue, consumption is everything and everything can be understood as consumption-similar to the "economic imperialism" debate some decades before. In this chapter, we problematize this perspective on the basis of Niklas Luhmann's general theory of society. We first introduce Luhmann's understanding of "audience roles" in the modern, primarily functionally differentiated world society and show then where he situated the consumer role within this society. Then we adopt this theoretical lens to explain why the universality thesis probably underestimates the successive risks if the consumer role would have already colonialized society so broadly and imposed its perpetual quest for experiences and pleasures upon all functional systems outside of the economy. We conclude by raising critical questions about the consequences that such a colonialization and a resulting functional de-differentiation could have for modern society.
International Review of Social History
Denounced by evangelical Christians, the Frankfurt School of neo-Marxists, new age cultists, and conservative and liberal moralists alike, consumerism has had a strange history as a subject of scholarship. Economics as a discipline has always assumed that demand played a central role in determining prosperity or poverty. Yet, only in the last thirty years has consumption, the purchase and use of goods and services by individuals, become a subject of systematic inquiry by historians and social scientists. Frank Trentmann, professor at Birkbeck College, University of London, is the world's foremost scholar on the history of what we buy. The "Cultures of Consumption" research program, which he led at the University of London from 2002 to 2007, generated an impressive set of scholarly studies that have defined the field. 1 His magnum opus, Empire of 1. Frank Trentmann (ed.
Mailbox: 2nd floor of Littauer Office Hours: By appointment Course Description This sophomore tutorial is an intensive course in the intellectual history of political economy. It will focus on exposing students to the great figures in the development of our discipline through a careful reading of their major works. Through this experience, students will not only improve their understanding of economic reasoning and analysis, but also gain a unique appreciation of how modern economics evolved into its present form. The first third of the course is devoted to classical economics. To set the scene for the rise of modern political economy, we will briefly discuss political debates on foreign trade and the national economy and early efforts at economic analysis in the 17th and 18th centuries, covering Mun, Petty, Hume, and Quesnay. We will then spend four weeks reading major works by Smith, Ricardo, Malthus, Say, Mill, and Marx. This section of the course will pay particular attention to classical ideas of price and value, distribution and social classes, population growth, economic growth and long-run trends, gluts and economic crises, the economic role of the state, and international trade. The second third of the course covers the rise of neoclassicism. We will read works by Jevons, Menger, Marshall, Edgeworth, Cournot, Walras, Pareto, Pigou, and others. In the process, we will seek to understand the new vision, tools of analysis, and assumptions that defined neoclassical economics, and we will relate this material both to the first part of the course and to what students have learned in their intermediate theory classes. Among other topics, we will discuss marginalism, general equilibrium, and welfare economics.
2015
1. Introduction 10 2. Cantillon 2.1 Introduction 16 2.2 Equilibrium prices and income distribution 2.3 Consumption and activity levels 2.4 Conclusion 3. Quesnay 29 3.1 Introduction 29 3.2 Bon prix and income distribution: the indeterminateness of profits 31 3.3 Sectoral quantity dynamics 3.4 Consumption propensities and activity levels 3.5 Conclusion 4. Turgot 42 6. Smith 68 6.1 Introduction 68 6.2 Natural prices and income distribution 70 6.3 Growth dynamics 6.4 Consumption and economic growth 78 6.5 Conclusion 7. Ricardo 82 7.1 Introduction 82 7.2 Theory of value and distribution 84 7.3 Theory of economic growth 90 7.4 The apparent irrelevance of demand 95 7.5 Conclusion 8. Sismondi 101 8.1 Introduction 8.2 Theory of value and distribution 8.3 Theory of economic growth 8.4 Consumption and economic growth 111 8.5 Conclusion 9. Malthus 9.1 Introduction 9.2 Theory of value and distribution 8 9.3 Theory of economic growth 126 9.4 Consumption and economic growth 9.5 Conclusion 135 10. Marx 10.1 Introduction 137 10.2 Theory of value and distribution 139 10.3 Theory of economic growth 143 10.4 The problem of demand deficiency 10.5 Conclusion 154 11. Kalecki and Classical Economics 11.1 Consumption demand and classical growth theory 156 11.2 Marx-Luxemburg-Kalecki 11.3 Kalecki, Keynes and classical economics 168 11.4 Conclusion: demand-led growth 12. Consumption and Demand-led Growth 180 12.1 A simple growth model 12.2 Growth through autonomous consumption 12.3 Demand-led growth and classical economics 191 13. Conclusion 198
The European Journal of the History of Economic Thought, 2009
In a new major work of critical recollection, Dimitris Milonakis and Ben Fine show how economics was once rich, diverse, multidimensional and pluralistic. The book details how political economy became economics through the desocialisation and dehistoricisation of the dismal science, accompanied by the separation of economics from other social sciences, especially economic history and sociology. It ranges over the shifting role of the historical and the social in economic theory, the shifting boundaries between the economic and the non-economic, all within a methodological context. Schools of thought and individuals, that have been neglected or marginalised, are treated in full, including classical political economy and Marx, the German and British Historical Schools, American institutionalism, Weber and Schumpeter and their programme of Sozialökonomik, and the Austrian School. Developments within the mainstream tradition from marginalism through Marshall and Keynes to general equilibrium theory are also scrutinised, and the clashes between the various camps from the famous Methodenstreit of the 1880s to the fierce debates of the 1930s and beyond brought to the fore. The prime rationale underpinning this account is to put the case for political economy back on the agenda. This is done by treating economics as a social science once again. It involves transcending the boundaries of the social sciences through the reintroduction and full incorporation of the social and the historical into the main corpus of political economy, by drawing on the rich traditions of the past. Economists, advanced students and researchers engaged in interdisciplinary approaches to the study of economic phenomena, scholars interested in the history of economic thought, economic historians and other social scientists will find this book of compelling interest.
PREFACE ix first aroused when a student of the former, and his lec tures were the nucleus of my later thinking. I am deeply indebted to both for many valuable suggestions concern ing form and diction.
Journal of Design History, 2000
Loading Preview
Sorry, preview is currently unavailable. You can download the paper by clicking the button above.