Academia.edu no longer supports Internet Explorer.
To browse Academia.edu and the wider internet faster and more securely, please take a few seconds to upgrade your browser.
1984, Journal of Public Economics
This paper presents a characterization of Lindahl allocations which makes no reference to personalized prices. Lindahl equilibria are characterized here by two conditions: Pareto efficiency and a voluntariness condition. Voluntariness requires that no consumer may benefit from a reduction in his contribution if this means that the vector of public goods must be reduced in the same proportion. The intersection of the (large) set of voluntary allocations and that of efficient ones turns out to be (under differentiability) the set of Lindahl allocations.
Review Economic Design, 2004
We study a continuous and balanced mechanism that is capable of implementing in Nash equilibrium all the Pareto-efficient individually rational allocations for an economy with public goods. The Government chooses a set of weights directly related to the Lindahl prices corresponding to the Pareto-efficient allocation it wants to implement. The mechanism then guarantees that initial endowments are re-allocated so that the chosen vector of Lindahl prices is indeed a Lindahl equilibrium, and implements the corresponding Lindahl allocation.
Econometrica, 1980
THE EXISTENCE OF EFFICIENT AND INCENTIVE COMPATIBLE EQUILIBRIA WITH PUBLIC GOODS' BY THEODORE GROVES AND JOHN 0. LEDYARD In our previous paper, "Optimal A'location of Public Goods ...," [5] we presented a mechanism for determining efficient, public goods allocations when preferences are unknown and consumers are free to misrepresent their demands for public goods. We proved the basic welfare theorem for this model: If consumers are competitive in markets for private goods and follow Nash behavior in their choice of demands to report to the mechanism, then equilibria will be Pareto optimal. In this paper we show this result is not vacuous by proving that an equilibrium will exist for a wide class of economies. Our conditions are slightly stronger than those required to prove the existence of a Lindahl equilibrium. In order to rule out the possibility of bankruptcy, we assume additionally that at all Pareto optimal allocations, private goods consumption is bounded away from zero. 1 This paper is a revision of reference [16] in our earlier paper, Groves and Ledyard [5]. We gratefuliy acknowledge support by National Science Foundation Grants SOC775-21820 and SOC76-20953 and a Fairchild Foundation Grant at California Institute of Technology where Ledyard was a Fairchild Scholar. We also would like to thank the referees and Michael Rothschild whose notes [8] and comments prompted us to complete this work. All errors are, of course, our own. 2 Hurwicz's paper was available in unpulished form in 1976. See Groves and Ledyard [5, Remark 4.3, p. 800]. 4 Lindahl allocations never leave a consumer worse off than at his initial endowment.
FinanzArchiv: Public Finance Analysis, 2006
Lindahl equilibria are often seen as an ideal outcome of cooperation in a public-goods economy. But it has also been observed that, if no transfer payments are possible, the Lindahl equilibrium may not be Pareto-superior to the Nash outcome of the voluntarycontribution game. We derive conditions under which agents (or countries in the case of an international public good) will prefer the Lindahl over the Nash solution. In particular we show that rich agents in general are better off in the Lindahl equilibrium than in the voluntary-contribution equilibrium. When the exogenously given income distribution is not skewed too much or the original economy is replicated sufficiently often, all agents will gain by the move from the Nash to the Lindahl outcome. The underlying effects are related to the famous exploitation of the rich by the poor countries occurring in Nash equilibrium (which follows from Warr neutrality) and the fact that the underprovision of the public good in Nash equilibrium is particularly serious in large economies. Finally, we tentatively discuss some potential applications concerning international cooperation on global public-good provision.
Aset of sufficiency conditions is presented forWalrasian equilibriumto be equivalent to voluntary and efficient allocations. An important corollary of this equivalence is that voluntary trade in non-clearing markets, which is omnipresent in all market economies, is inefficient. Moreover, our assumptions generalize all the results on the Pareto-efficiency properties of disequilibrium. This generalization also shows that the inefficiency of disequilibrium is germane to the existence ofWalrasian equilibrium.
SSRN Electronic Journal, 2000
Preliminary version: 2014 July 11th, typeset from …le corchonHamSempG.tex.
Economics Letters, 2012
We extend Bergstrom and Cornes (1983) to show that for strong independence of efficient allocations from distribution in a public goods economy, the utility functions of all consumers must identically be of the form: A (Y) X i , where Y and X i are respectively the quantities of public good and private good for consumer i, and A(•) is some arbitrary function. This implies that for an economy with heterogeneous consumer preferences, it is impossible to ensure that any redistribution of private goods will remain efficient, especially for boundary Pareto optima.
Review of Economic Design, 2009
Groves and Ledyard (Econometrica 45:783-809, 1977) constructed a mechanism attaining Pareto efficient allocations in the presence of public goods. After this path-breaking paper, many mechanisms have been proposed to attain desirable allocations with public goods. Thus, economists have thought that the free-rider problem is solved, in theory. Our view to this problem is not so optimistic. Rather, we propose fundamental impossibility theorems with public goods. In the previous mechanism design, it was implicitly assumed that every agent must participate in the mechanism that the designer provides. This approach neglects one of the basic features of public goods: non-excludability. We explicitly incorporate non-excludability and then show that it is impossible to construct a mechanism in which every agent has an incentive to participate. We thank an anonymous referee and Takeshi Suzuki for useful comments.
ISER Discussion Paper, 2001
Groves-Ledyard (1977) constructed a mechanism attaining Pareto efficient allocations in the presence of public goods. After this path-breaking paper, many mechanisms have been proposed to attain desirable allocations with public goods. Thus, economists have thought that the ...
Journal of Economic Theory, 1991
Journal of Mathematical Economics, 1977
This paper characterizes Pareto efficient allocations by means of prices within a public-goods economy. The underlying notion of public commodities is a generalization covering private and pure public ones as extreme cases. The model uses as measure space of agents.
The Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 2003
Wicksell's and Lindahl's ideas on public goods and decisions are reviewed in light of later developments in the theoretical economics literature. I begin by discussing their normative ideals, in particular the notion of justness, and the sources of the difficulties in reaching them. Wicksell's and Lindahl's ideal states, as well as the obstacles that they perceive, are compared to more recent views on free riding and on the behavior of elected representatives. Their views on political bargaining are then related to later concepts, in particular to the core of the economy.
SSRN Electronic Journal, 2021
* We are deeply indebted to Andreu Mas-Colell for useful comments and suggestions, with the usual caveat. 1 See Silvestre (2003) for a discussion.
International Tax and Public Finance, 2008
Applying a willingness-to-pay approach known from contingent valuation in environmental economics we first develop an ordinally based specific measure for the size of individual sacrifice that is connected with an agent's contribution to a public good. We then construct a selection mechanism that picks the unique efficient solution among all allocations that have an equal sacrifice as defined in this way. We show that the solution thus obtained not only corresponds to the egalitarian equivalent public good allocation devised by Moulin but also that it has much in common with the much older Lindahl equilibrium. Moreover, the equal sacrifice solutions as characterized in this paper fulfil the ability-to-pay as well as the benefit principle.
Lindahl equilibrium is an application of price-taking behavior to achieve efficiency in the allocation of public goods. Such an equilibrium requires individuals to be strategically naive, i.e., Lindahl equilibrium is not incentive compatible. Correlated equilibrium is defined precisely to take account of strategic behavior and incentive compatibility. Using the duality theory of linear programming, we show that these two seemingly disparate notions can be combined to give a public goods, Lindahl pricing characterization of efficient correlated equilibria. We also show that monopoly theory can be used to characterize inefficient correlated equilibria.
Research Papers in Economics, 2004
This paper seeks to reopen a discussion that the profession has considered settled and closed, namely, the issue of the optimal quantity of a public good to supply. Its focus is on the determination of the optimal quantity to supply of a public good in the Pigovian model as popularized by Musgrave. It argues that the vertical summation of the individual demand curves in the Pigovian model is as inappropriate as the rejected horizontal summation of individuals' consumption of public goods. The horizontal summation is inconsistent with the physical realities of public good supply suggesting an mmultiple of the quantity that is actually available, which is an illusion. The vertical summation while having the advantage of informing on efficiency taxes and equitable cost sharing formula suffers from the fallacy of aggregation and exaggerates the aggregate demand for public goods, thus misleading supply decisions. This realization comes from reckoning with the basic properties of pure public goods in particular nonrivalry-the joint supply property. Given this property, the paper submits that the optimal quantity of a public good is the largest quantity demanded by any single consumer (individually or as a collective). A corollary of this is that public goods consumption is not validly subject to aggregation by any means. Aggregation is irrelevant and that individual demand curves or schedules are required only for the determination of optimal benefit taxes and equitable cost sharing formula. That is, the individual demand curves for a public good or service should be considered only for the purpose of determining each person's fair and equitable share of the cost of supply (i.e. based on the individuals' marginal valuations) as shown in Figure 4. In other words, the so-called (collective) willingness to pay curve is only confusing issues and hence not required. This in no way implies the consumption of separate quantities to be added up. Rather, it stages the consumption of the same quantity by all with different payments that are added up to finance the supply, which conforms to the Pigovian solution and indeed all the solutions that have been advanced. Yet, it is unique from the earlier solutions. An equitable cost sharing formula that guarantees an efficient financing scheme is also proposed. It is a benefit share weighted cost sharing formula, which obviates the potential threat of fiscal drag. It is found that barring information failure, the public budget should ordinarily be enjoying surplus under optimal benefit taxes. That is with optimal benefit taxes, balanced budget is within easy reach with relief for taxpayers in relation to service benefits enjoyed and therefore, less resentment to taxation could be anticipated. These observations and findings need to be given serious thoughts. Though, the rationale for government intervention in an otherwise market economy is primarily seen in market failure, the ultimate justification is the gain in welfare from the achievement of Pareto improvements in resource allocation. It follows that the possibility of further Pareto improvements in welfare must be a welcome development. JEL: H41
Documentos De Trabajo De La Facultad De Ciencias Economicas Y Empresariales, 1988
We show that if there are Constant Returns to Scale in the production of the public good a) Any Lindahl equilibrium (L.E) is a Nash equilib::,ium (N.E.) in a price-setting game, b) not all N.E. are L.E., but just those fo::, which the production of the public good is positive and c) the set of L.E. and Strong Equilibria coincide. However if the supply function is continuously differenti_ able,L.E. is never a N.E. We end the paper with sorne general comments about the nature of the incentive problem.
Journal of Economic Theory, 1989
We offer a new formalization of Lindahl's equilibrium notion for public goods which yields an endogenous theory of profit distribution in line with the benefit approach to taxation. Increasing returns in the production of public goods are not a priori excluded. Our equilibrium notion coincides with Kaneko's "Ratio Equilibrium" for economies with only one public good. By reinterpreting the commodity space, the equilibrium concept can be applied to economies with purely private goods or with externalities, In the pure private good case, our concept singles out allocations that are efficient and where individual net payments agree with average cost.
Topics in Theoretical Economics, 2000
Journal of Public Economics, 2005
This paper argues that, in models with heterogeneous agents, the concept of the marginal cost of public funds (MCPF) will only be useful if it is compared with an analogous concept for the benefit side. The MCPF does not assume a unique value and is not particularly illuminating in and out of itself. Also gone is the benchmark status of MCPF = 1. Turning to the provision of public goods, using a mechanism design approach, the paper constructs a two-stage proof for Kaplow's [Kaplow, L., 1996. The optimal supply of public goods and the distortionary cost of taxation. National Tax Journal 49, 513-533.] proposition concerning the birrelevanceQ of labor supply and distributional concerns in public good provision. This highlights the two fundamental ingredients for his result. First, the provision of public goods per se, when it satisfies the Samuelson's rule, is only potentially Pareto-improving. Second, the actual Pareto improvement will materialize when, or if, one reforms the income tax structure. If the reform is not forthcoming, the decision on public goods provision must rely on redistributional concerns. Finally, the paper generalizes Broadway and Keen's [Boadway, R., Keen, M., 1993. Public goods, self-selection and optimal income taxation. International Economic Review 34, 463-478.] result to a model with many types of agents, many private goods and without making any assumptions regarding which self-selection constraints are or are not binding.
We show that if there are Constant Returns to Scale in the production of the public good a) Any Lindahl equilibrium (L.E) is a Hash equilib:-iurn (N.E.) in a price-setting game, b) not all N.E. ~-e L.E., but just those fo:-which the production of the public good is positive and c) the set of L.E. and Strong Equilibria coincide. However if the supply function is continuously differentiable,L.E. is never a N.E. We end the paper with sorne general comments about the nature of the incentive problem. (*) An earlier version of this paper benefited from cornments of A. Mas-Colell and R. Repullo .
We show that if there are Constant Returns to Scale in the production of the public good a) Any Lindahl equilibrium (L.E) is a Hash equilib:-iurn (N.E.) in a price-setting game, b) not all N.E. ~-e L.E., but just those fo:-which the production of the public good is positive and c) the set of L.E. and Strong Equilibria coincide. However if the supply function is continuously differentiable,L.E. is never a N.E. We end the paper with sorne general comments about the nature of the incentive problem. (*) An earlier version of this paper benefited from cornments of A. Mas-Colell and R. Repullo .
Loading Preview
Sorry, preview is currently unavailable. You can download the paper by clicking the button above.