Academia.edu no longer supports Internet Explorer.
To browse Academia.edu and the wider internet faster and more securely, please take a few seconds to upgrade your browser.
2014
We ask whether the institutions introduced in Chinese Treaty Ports by Western powers from 1842 to 1943 had an impact on capital market development in China as evidenced by interest rates. We estimate annual interest rates for 205 prefectures throughout China over the years 1820-1911 by measuring carrying costs of grain. The key finding are: first, that interest rates in China rose during the 19th century, and were on the whole higher than they were in the 18th century. Second, difference-in-differences estimation shows that treaty port institutions lowered interest rates significantly, not only in the immediate vicinity of the treaty ports but more broadly. The magnitude of the decline was about 25%. 1 Hoover Institution, Stanford University, 434 Galvez, Stanford, CA 94304. Also affiliated with NBER and CEPR. Email: [email protected] 2 Hoover Institution, Stanford University, 434 Galvez, Stanford, CA 94304. Also affiliated with NBER and CEPR. Email: [email protected] ...
2015
Does the difference in capital market development between major advanced economies during the 18 th and 19 th centuries explain the subsequent divergence in their income levels? We employ a storage model to obtain regional interest rates from monthly grain price changes, and we compare the integration of capital markets in Britain and China. The first step is to validate the approach by showing that grain price-based interest rates match salient features of the 19 th century U.S. capital market. Our analysis using almost 20,000 new interest rates reveals that Britain's rates were lower than China's, even compared to China's more developed areas, although not by a large margin. The regional integration of capital markets in Britain was substantially higher than in China, however, indicating lower barriers to capital flows than in China. At distances above 200 kilometers regional interest rates in British regions are about three times as strongly correlated as interest rates in China. Our results show that while China appears not to have been as capitalscarce as generally presumed, it had a strong disadvantage relative to Britain in its ability to allocate capital to the location of efficient use. Overall these results suggest that capital market performance may have been an important reason behind the divergence in incomes across countries in the 18 th and 19 th century.
2016
Uneven development within countries suggests that domestic trade frictions are important. Trade flows within a country, however, are rarely observed. We employ a new dataset on trade between fifteen Chinese treaty ports to examine the importance of domestic frictions around the year 1900. The distribution of welfare effects depends on each port's productivity and factor costs, China's economic geography as it influences trade costs, as well as the degree of regional diversity in production, which increases the potential gains from trade. We utilize this framework to quantify the size and distribution of welfare effects resulting from new technology and lower trade costs. Domestic trade frictions turn out to be substantial, far from the frictionless world that is commonly assumed. Moreover, geographic barriers loom large in shaping the welfare gains from technology improvements and trade cost reductions. We find, however, that an important explanation for why there was a limit to what could be gained through increased domestic trade was that the differences in productivity across regions of China in the 19th century were relatively low. Keywords: domestic trade frictions, welfare gains from trade, 19th century China
Western powers have always tried to penetrate China’s economy and get what it can, knowing that the empire has a lot to offer. At best, they were given very limited access through the Canton system, ensuring that the Chinese still benefitted in the end of every commercial transaction with the outsiders. But the opium wars, together with the assertiveness of Britain, aided the western powers to open China to trade and eventually establish their economic interests within. The treaty port is indeed a manifestation of western commercial institutions slowly creeping in to China to realize the potential gains of the huge economy. This has also provided them with the opportunity to influence the empire to inevitably support the rising economic order, which is based on high degrees of economic openness. With the presence of these enclaves, it is natural to ask what has been the impact of open ports under foreign control to the areas where they were established, and to China’s economy as a whole. In essence, this kind of questioning tries to see what has been the impact of western imperialism to a huge empire like China. The existing literature on this topic has dwelled on this question through different approaches and through different foci that led them to different conclusions. This paper has provided a systematic narrative explanation of the current existing ideas through a review of the relevant literature on the treaty ports and on China’s economy during the late Qing empire. This paper specifically looks at (1) development within the treaty ports, and the (2) impact this had in China’s economy. With the great deal of difficulty involved in trying to obtain primary data on trade and China’s economy during the Qing empire, the general review also emphasized empirical data compiled by the different authors in building on the objectives of this paper.
Explorations in Economic History, 1969
Roughly one century after the establishment of regular foreign trade at Canton, mounting friction led to the Opium War of 184& 1842, after which the victorious foreigners gained control of several enclaves, or treaty ports, on the China coast. Both in the newly opened treaty ports and in Hong Kong, initial commercial expansion resulted from close cooperation among foreign administrators and traders and a body of Cantonese merchants who moved with the trade, some dealing independently while others worked for foreign merchant houses. By 1860, following eighteen years of adjustment and conflict culminating in the wars of 1856 and 1860, the treaties of Tientsin and Peking and the formation of a foreign-controlled Imperial Maritime Customs Administration, with the attendant regularization of duties, showed that a balance of power and responsibility in treaty port and trade administration had emerged. This paper seeks to approach an understanding of treaty port commerce by focusing on the role of the native mercantile community and of Chinese commercial institutions in the treaty ports between 1860 and 1875. Our conclusions relating to the status and significance of indigenous mercantile activity, within and outside the treaty ports, contrast sharply with the viewpoints taken in several historical and sociological studies. If confirmed by subsequent investigations, these conclusions necessitate the reexamination of certain aspects of China's economic, political, and even intellectual history; a final sec-*It gives me great pleasure to express my gratitude to Professor Knight Biggerstaff and to Mrs. Jane Leonard, both of Cornell University, and to my wife Evelyn for their valuable criticism of various drafts of this paper. Much of the research was carried out during the author's tenure as a National Science Foundation Graduate Fellow.
This paper reviews recent revisionist studies of imperialism that demonstrate the complexities behind the late Qing state's strategy to accommodate to new challenges born out of foreign conflicts exacerbated by domestic crises. These publications have pointed scholars away from the exclusivity of external agency to the making of modern China. But looking at the role of globalization adds another dimension to understanding how imperialism engaged late Qing China's public finance system and indigenous banking institutions. China's centuries-old experience with global trade previous to the nineteenth century did not prepare the country for world-wide recession, and consequently, foreign banks acquiring a hold on the government's purse by the last decades of that century. From a 'broadbrush' perspective, the paper argues state-sponsored attempts at reform of public finance came too late, and in the long-term had grave repercussions.
China Review International, 1998
The American Economic Review, 2007
Why did Western Europe industrialize first? An influential view holds that its exceptionally well-functioning markets supported with a certain set of institutions provided the incentives to make investments needed to industrialize. This paper examines this hypothesis by comparing the actual performance of markets in terms of market integration in Western Europe and China, two regions that were relatively advanced in the preindustrial period, but would start to industrialize about 150 years apart. We find that the performance of markets ...
Edward Elgar Publishing eBooks, 2022
Business History, 2018
Book review by Richard Von Glahn at Business History.
Historia crítica, 2023
Objective/Context: This article surveys the evolution of commercial finance in Ming-Qing China and responds to the debates about the role of finance in the "Great Divergence" between China and Europe. Methodology: Based on new historical materials, especially commercial documents, we study the evolution of financial organizations at different levels as delineated by Fernand Braudel. We also analyze the long-run trends of commercial interest rates in the Ming-Qing eras based on a novel historical database of interest rates in China. Originality: This article explores capital market developments since the 16th century and their relationship with the state-a topic that has been almost entirely neglected in the existing literature. We also find improvements in market integration in China before the late 19th century when Western financial institutions began to enter China, and the prime commercial interest rate in the capital market was much lower than the dominant accounts in the "Great Divergence" debate. Conclusions: While current comparative studies either emphasize the financial stagnation of Ming-Qing China relative to the West or emphasize its special development through non-market mechanisms, e.g., clans, this article shows that the capital market played a similar key role in the evolution of finance in Ming-Qing China as it did in advanced parts of Europe. Thus, we suggest that the difference in financial development between China and the West lies in the organizational structure of the financial sector and the relationship between finance and the state.
American Economic Review, 2002
Trade has been considered a condition for growth and development, a view that might have merits in explaining the rise of the Western world. I use a new data set from archival sources of eighteenth-century China to revisit this question. This analysis suggests previous studies of market integration, which attribute much growth to a reduction in transport costs, have overestimated these effects. I find the overall level of market integration in China was higher than previously thought, and, intertemporal effects are important substitutes for trade. Both factors reduce the importance of trade as a unique explanation for subsequent growth.
The Economic History Review, 2007
In this paper we review evidence about the development of the Chinese capital markets over a crucial period in world market history, and place that development in the context of world financial markets at the time. Despite fundamental differences between China today and China 100 years ago, it is still important to consider the dangers of an imbalance between domestic and international investor markets, and the mismatch between domestic and foreign expectations about investor protection. The lessons of the last century suggest that China today should consider opening Chinese investor access to foreign capital markets in order to equilibrate the level of diversification between foreign and domestic investors. In addition, protection of domestic corporate investor rights is at least as important as protecting foreign investor rights.
Economic History Review, 2007
In this paper we review evidence about the development of the Chinese capital markets over a crucial period in world market history, and place that development in the context of world financial markets at the time. Despite fundamental differences between China today and China 100 years ago, it is still important to consider the dangers of an imbalance between domestic and international investor markets, and the mismatch between domestic and foreign expectations about investor protection. The lessons of the last century suggest that China today should consider opening Chinese investor access to foreign capital markets in order to equilibrate the level of diversification between foreign and domestic investors. In addition, protection of domestic corporate investor rights is at least as important as protecting foreign investor rights.
SSRN Electronic Journal, 2000
The Wharton Financial Institutions Center provides a multidisciplinary research approach to the problems and opportunities facing the financial services industry in its search for competitive excellence. The Center's research focuses on the issues related to managing risk at the firm level as well as ways to improve productivity and performance. The Center fosters the development of a community of faculty, visiting scholars and Ph.D. candidates whose research interests complement and support the mission of the Center. The Center works closely with industry executives and practitioners to ensure that its research is informed by the operating realities and competitive demands facing industry participants as they pursue competitive excellence. Copies of the working papers summarized here are available from the Center. If you would like to learn more about the Center or become a member of our research community, please let us know of your interest.
International Journal of Asian Studies, 2023
The financial burden of the Boxer Indemnity forced the Chinese government to change its behaviours since 1901. This article reexamines the position that the decision to honour indeminity obligations enabled the Chinese state to maintain peaceful relations with western powers during the first quarter of the twentiety century. The 1901 edict affirming that China would reexamine its capacity to satisfy its international commitments. Before this edict, China had selectively followed its Sino-foreign treaties, but thereafter, China completely assumed all of her financial obligations to foreign creditors. These changes in behaviour helped China restore its deteriorated foreign relations and were followed by Provisional Executive Duan Qirui until 1925. These changes can be illustrated by three cases, namely the depreciation of tael, the Austrian loans, and the gold franc. The cases were highly international as the first concerned eleven foreign creditors, the second concerned two, and the third concerned three. From 1901-1925, foreign powers also provided China with reciprocal favours in exchange for China's responsible behaviours. Eventually, China retrieved its tariff autonomy in 1930.
Transformations in Banking, Finance and Regulation, 2022
Études et Documents is a working papers series. Working Papers are not refereed, they constitute research in progress. Responsibility for the contents and opinions expressed in the working papers rests solely with the authors. Comments and suggestions are welcome and should be addressed to the authors.
2016
This paper reconstructs China's economic development between 1840 and 1912 with an estimation of Gross Domestic Product (GDP). It provides for the first time a time series of GDP (per capita) for the late Qing Dynasty (1644-1911), based on sectoral output and value added, in current as well as in constant prices. The present estimation of per capita GDP in the late Qing period comes out higher than previous estimations, but it still suggests low average levels of Chinese living standards. The economy during the late Qing Empire was characterised by a large and growing agricultural sector and displayed only minor structural changes. Only in the beginning of the twentieth century did the economy start to show signs of growth.
Journal of Urban History
China was forced to open itself to trade by the Western powers in the nineteenth century. Led by the British, these powers wanted to ensure they were able to import their goods (the most lucrative being opium) and waged two wars to do so. The First Opium War was fought between 1839 and 1842, and the Second (also known as the Arrow War) from 1856 to 1860. These Wars led to a series of treaties, beginning with the Treaty of Nanking (signed with the British on August 29, 1842), which ended the First Opium War; the Second Opium War led to the Treaty of Tientsin (actually a series of agreements with Britain and France ending the first phase of the conflict, and signed in June 1858) and the Convention of Peking (three treaties, with Britain, France, and Russia, respectively, signed on November 14, 1860). Known collectively as the "unequal treaties," these were only three of a number of such "agreements" foisted on an unwilling China and rightly seen as a low point in the country's history. The Treaty of Nanking ceded Hong Kong Island to Britain in perpetuity and stipulated that five ports were to be opened to foreign trade: Canton (Guangzhou), Amoy (Xiamen), Foochow (Fuzhou), Ningpo (Ningbo), and Shanghai. These became known as Treaty Ports and were the first in an ever-increasing series of settlements that spread themselves across the country until January 11, 1943, when the Chinese and the British signed the Treaty for the Relinquishment of ExtraTerritorial Rights in China, ending the system after 101 years. A number of recently published books examine the Treaty Ports, as well as their genesis, and influence on urbanization in China. The reissuing of Jacques M. Downs's The Golden Ghetto: The American Commercial Community at Canton and the Shaping of American China Policy, 1784-1844 portrays the American community at Canton in the decades up to the First Opium War-a period culminating with the Sino-American Treaty of Wanghia (July 3, 1844). This was a treaty that not only stressed international friendship but also introduced the concept of "extraterritoriality" (immunity to prosecution for foreigners under Chinese law). Robert Nield's China's
Loading Preview
Sorry, preview is currently unavailable. You can download the paper by clicking the button above.